Endogenous economic growth with disembodied knowledge

AuthorCarla Marchese,Fabio Privileggi
Date01 June 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12284
Published date01 June 2018
Received: 26 September 2017 Accepted: 7 November2017
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12284
ARTICLE
Endogenous economic growth with disembodied
knowledge
Carla Marchese1Fabio Privileggi2
1InstitutePOLIS - DiGSPES, Università del
PiemonteOrientale “Amedeo Avogadro”
2Departmentof Economics and Statistics
“Cognettide Martiis”, Università di Torino
CarlaMarchese, Institute POLIS - DiGSPES,
Universitàdel Piemonte Orientale “Amedeo
Avogadro”,ViaCavour 84, 15121 Alessandria,
Italy(carla.marchese@uniupo.it).
FabioPrivileggi, Department of Economics and
Statistics“Cognetti de Martiis”,Università di
Torino,Lungo DoraSiena 100 A, 10153 Torino,
Italy(fabio.privileggi@unito.it).
CarlaMarchese acknowledges the financial
supportfrom Università del Piemonte Orientale.
Mainstream endogenous growth models assume that new knowl-
edge is embodied into either new intermediate or final goods,
monopolistically supplied by the patent holder.Recent technological
progress,however, often gives rise to pure intellectual contents, such
as software codes or business models, directly usable in the produc-
tion of final goods. Once a content of this type has been produced,
it is in fixed supply, that is, the inventor can only rent it out (orsell
it) or not; hence, the quantity restriction typical of monopoly cannot
arise, while competition is viable. We show that, however,as long as
the inventor owning a patent can control through license activation
devices the access to the intellectual content of the workers using
herinvention in the final goods production, monopolistic exploitation
becomes viable and will occur.It turns out that in this framework, the
income share of labor is smaller than in the Lab-Equipment economy,
which represents the setting closest to our model. Moreover, with
elastic labor supply labor employment is also negatively impacted.
Thisimplies that some standard public policiesdevised for correcting
inefficiencies in development mayperform poorly in this framework.
1INTRODUCTION
In the recent past one way of highlighting the pace of technological progress was to quote the Moore law, describ-
ing the expected improvements in a widely used intermediate good, the semiconductor. Nowadays, however, tech-
nological progress appears largely disembodied, and characterized by the supply of new immaterial goods such as
DNA sequences, software codes, computer programs, Internet applications, business models, and so on, which are
patentable1and directly usable in the final goods production, without having to be incorporated into capital or inter-
mediate inputs. This feature does not fit well into standard endogenous growth models,2which assume that, in a sys-
tem with intellectual property rights (IPRs), the successful inventor has the opportunity of becoming the sole supplier
1Thistrend for the United States can be dated back to 1998, when in the so-called State Street Bank case, a business method was declared patentable. Many
other similar rulings followed with respect to software. A 2014 Supreme Court decision stated that the claim for a patent must contain more than abstract
ideas of general character; it must be based, e.g., on unconventionalsteps that confine it to a particular useful application. For patentability in general, see
Eckertand Langinier (2013).
2Like,e.g., in Romer (1990) and the so-called Lab-Equipment model in chapter 13 of Acemoglu (2009).
Journal of Public Economic Theory.2018;20:437–449. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet c
2017 Wiley Periodicals,Inc. 437

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT