Employee treatment and firm innovation

AuthorConnie X. Mao,Jamie Weathers
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jbfa.12393
Published date01 July 2019
Date01 July 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jbfa.12393
Employee treatment and firm innovation
Connie X. Mao1Jamie Weathers2
1FoxSchool of Business, Temple University,
Philadelphia, USA
2Department of Finance and Commercial Law,
Haworth College of Business, WesternMichigan
University, USA
Correspondence
ConnieX. Mao, Department of Finance, Fox
Schoolof Business, Temple University,Philadel-
phia,PA 19122.
Email:cmao@temple.edu
Abstract
We identify firm innovation as a channel through which the treat-
ment of employees affects firm value. Long-term incentive theory
supports positive effects of ‘good’ employee treatment on innova-
tion. Alternatively, entrenchment theory suggests such treatment
will lead to complacency and shirking, hence deterring innovation.
These opposing views merit investigation since human capital is
increasingly essential to the growth and success of a firm. Using the
KLD database and patent/citationdata, we find a significant positive
relationship between favorable employee treatment and the inno-
vation quantity and quality of a firm. Furthermore, we find that the
positive treatment of employees improves innovation focus – more
innovation related to firms’ core business, leading to greater firm
value via the increased economic value of patents. These findings,
robust to endogeneity concerns, provide support for the long-term
incentive hypothesis, suggesting that well-treated employees
increase firm innovation. Thus, firm innovation represents a channel
through which positive employeetreatment enhances firm value.
KEYWORDS
corporate social responsibility (CSR), employee treatment, human
capital, patents and citations, technological innovation
JEL CLASSIFICATION
G3, J24, M14, O31
1INTRODUCTION
It is often contended that employeesare the most valuable asset of a firm and an essential source of competitive advan-
tage (Coff,1997). This is particularly true with respect to firm innovation. For example, Laszlo Bock, former Senior VP
of Google’s People Operations, commented on Google’s aptitude for creating an environment of innovation through
employee empowerment:
Google has been keeping the pipeline of innovation going by tapping its employees and letting ideas percolate
up Personally,I believe this culture is an insight about the human condition. People look for meaning in their
J Bus Fin Acc. 2019;46:977–1002. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jbfa c
2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 977
978 MAO ANDWEATHERS
work. People want to know what’s happening in their environment. People want to havesome ability to shape
that environment.1
This approach to a ‘cultureof innovation’ is necessary for firm survival as it is a strong source of competitive advan-
tage(Zingales, 2000). However, a central challenge in motivating employees arises when the interests of employeesand
thefirm are misaligned, and the efforts of employees cannot be perfectly observed. These circumstances create a moral
hazard problem where employees may haveincentives to exert low levels of effort to enjoy the ‘quiet life’ (Bertrand &
Mullainathan, 2003).
Researchers have focused on the design of monetary incentives, linking employee compensation to firms’ eco-
nomic outcomes via performance pay to mitigate the moral hazard problem between employees and the firm
(Holmstrom, 1979). However, monetary incentives often provide only relatively weak association between pay
and performance due to concerns about inequality and overconfidence (Larkin, Pierce, & Gino, 2012). Further,
employees are only motivated by monetary incentives up to a certain point, beyond which non-pecuniary incen-
tives, such as fair treatment and job satisfaction, are required to generate more firm value (Cerasoli, Ford, &
Nicklin, 2014). Building on recent literature in which a firm’s treatment of its employees affects the value of
the firm – either directly through shareholder value (e.g., Edmans, 2011; Faleye & Trahan, 2011) or indirectly
via capital structure (e.g., Bae, Kang, & Wang, 2011; Berk, Stanton, & Zechner, 2010; Verwijmeren & Derwall,
2010) – we propose corporate innovation as a new channel through which employee treatment affects firm
value.
In this paper, we investigate the effect of employee treatment on firm innovation, based on the literature and
prevailing views. There are two opposing views of the effect. The first view is that positive employee treatment
enhances firm innovation. Many of the components in positive employee treatment (or satisfaction) are conducive
to a corporate culture of failure tolerance, exploitation protection, and an engaging work environment. Innova-
tive projects typically involve high risk, long-term horizons, and often many failures before successes. Job secu-
rity often promotes a failure-tolerant work environment, which in turn provides motivation for employees to inno-
vate (i.e., participate in tasks with a high probability of failure) (Manso, 2011). Exploitation protection represents
a positive culture of managerial ethics and integrity, which in turn reduces the fear of being exploited or having
ideas expropriated, hence encouraging employees to invest more in firm-specific human capital to develop inno-
vative projects (Carmeli, Reiter-Palmon, & Ziv, 2010). Finally, a favorable work setting reflects an environment
focusing on teamwork and citizenship. Innovation often involves collaboration, whereby a corporate culture of
good teamwork and respect will foster productive collaborations, thus enhancing innovation (Folkestad& Gonzalez,
2010).
The second view is that positive employeetreatment may hinder innovation. Cronqvist, Heyman, Nilsson, Svaleryd,
and Vlachos (2009) suggest that entrenched managers receive private benefits such as fewer union negotiation
attemptsand better social relationships with employees by paying workers more. As a result, favorable employeetreat-
ment may be conducive to a work environment where both managers and employees enjoy the ‘quietlife’. Similarly,
union-controlled firms via employee stock ownership plans (ESOPs) tend to enhance participants’ personal benefits
rather than maximizing shareholder value (Faleye, Mehrotra, & Morck, 2006). Further, Atanassov (2013) documents
that job security due to anti-takeover laws causes a lower levelof firm innovation. Consequently, favorable employee
treatment could deter firm innovation.
To study the impact of positive employee treatment on firm innovation, we employ data from two independent
sources as employee treatment proxies: the KLD Research & Analytics, Inc. SOCRATESdatabase (KLD) and Fortune’s
100 Best Companies to Work For R
lists (the Best Companies list or BC list). We use patent and citation information
1http://www.forbes.com/sites/laurahe/2013/03/29/googles-secrets-of-innovation-empowering-its-employees/.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT