Education stock and its implication for income inequality: The case of Asian economies

AuthorNoman Arshed,Muhammad Shahid Hassan,Samra Bukhari,Awais Anwar
Date01 May 2019
Published date01 May 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12585
1050
|
wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/rode Rev Dev Econ. 2019;23:1050–1066.
© 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
1
|
INTRODUCTION
The persistent rise in inequality around the globe over the last two decades from 1990 to 2010 led to
a growing concern for worldwide policy makers (Wolf, 2015). The unequal distribution of economic
resources among individuals and flow resources that are increasing between the rich and the poor is
known as income inequality (Todaro & Smith, 2015). Oxfam (2017) reveals that 1% of the richest peo-
ple owned more wealth than the rest of planet. However, the income of the poorest 10% has increased
DOI: 10.1111/rode.12585
REGULAR ARTICLE
Education stock and its implication for income
inequality: The case of Asian economies
NomanArshed1
|
AwaisAnwar2
|
Muhammad ShahidHassan1
|
SamraBukhari1
1Department of Economics,University
of Management and Technology, Lahore,
Pakistan
2Department of Economics,The University
of Lahore, Lahore, Pakistan
Correspondence
Awais Anwar, Department of Economics,
The University of Lahore, Lahore,
Pakistan.
Email: awaisanwar007@yahoo.com
Abstract
This study develops a quadratic relationship between educa-
tion and income inequality among Asian developing econo-
mies for the period from 1960 to 2015. Panel cointegration
and fully modified OLS is applied for the estimation of
long- run coefficients. The results show that initial, primary,
secondary, and tertiary enrollment increases inequality.
However, the effect of education on income inequality be-
comes negative after a certain threshold level (i.e., 97.5%
for primary, 43.5% for secondary, and 11% for tertiary).
Thus, this result proves the Kuznets phenomenon of an in-
verted U- shape relationship for primary, secondary, and ter-
tiary enrollments.
JEL CLASSIFICATION
I24, O15, O53
KEYWORDS
education—income inequality Kuznets curve, panel cointegration, panel
FMOLS
|
1051
ARSHED EtAl.
by only $3.00, while the income of the richest 1% have increased 182 times. According to a study of
Vietnam, the richest man earns more in a day that a poor man earns in 10 years. Byanyima (2017)
confirms that 35 people have more resources than 50% of the world's population. However, the pres-
ent situation shows that eight richest people own the same amount of resources as 50% of the world's
population. Benabou (1996) shows that half of the world's poor population owns less than 10% of its
wealth. However, several studies indicate that developing economies can reduce income inequality by
increasing the level of education in their country. Housing prices in urban areas are erratic in the EU
because of increasing income inequality (Inchauste, Karver, Kim, & Jelil, 2018), which is the highest
over the past three decades from 1980 to 2015 (Cohen & Ladaique, 2018).
Development theory mainly discusses the disparity in income, health, education, and living stan-
dards among people. People cannot reach their optimal potential, so they cannot obtain more resources
(Harriet, 2010; Hills, 2010). Furthermore, inequality only favors those who have political muscle,
while creating negative externalities for others (Krueger, 2018). At the initial stages of development,
inequality increases owing to an increase in economic growth stemming from increases in the in-
comes of people in business, but as time passes, the trickle- down effect reduces the level of inequality
because businesses pay higher taxes, which are then spent on public goods, or because they demand
more labor for expansion. This implies a nonlinear relationship between income inequality and devel-
opment. This phenomenon creates a difficulty in handling economic growth for countries that have a
low level of development (Aghion, Caroli, & Garcia- Penalosa, 1999; Kuznets, 1955).
However, changes in economic growth are not the only factors that affect income inequality; skilled
and nonskilled labor forces also exhibit certain variations in income inequality. A higher proportion
of a skilled labor force will reduce wage premiums because of the shortage of labor that decreases the
level of wage inequality (Krueger, 2018; Lakner & Milanovic, 2016; Loayza & Raddatz, 2010; Ruffin,
2009). Additionally, there are two main scenarios: one is the scenario of education, and the other is the
scenario of noneducation. An increase in education will lead to a decrease in the income of a country
because of technology and innovation. This scenario will decrease the difference between wages and
reduce income inequality. Hopefully, the proportion of skilled labor force is likely to rise up to 45.5%
by 2030 around the globe. Furthermore, an increase in unskilled labor affects the schooling and ageing
of the population in the world labor market, and this will lead to an increase in the skill premium in
the scenario of increasing education and, thus, further increase the income inequality (Dixon, 2003).
The objective of our study is to present a dynamic panel investigation of the effect of education
on income inequality. This objective was selected because an increase in the skilled labor force will
decrease the level of income inequality, but in the case of Asian economies, income inequality and
skilled labor force have been increasing for the past few decades from 1995 to 2014.1 A key feature of
our study is the inclusion of a specific level of education and its impact on income inequality because
the skilled labor force includes those people who attain 9, or more than 9, years of education.2 In
our model, we also include the labor force that attains less than 9 years of education. The study also
investigates the law of diminishing returns and its implications for the education and income inequal-
ity relationship, bearing in mind the specific levels of education. The effect of education on income
inequality has been studied by many researchers (Arshed, Anwar, Kousar, & Bukhari, 2018; Barro,
1999; Checchi, 2001; Gregorio & Lee, 2002; Karim, 2015), but they did not discuss different levels of
education and the implication of the law of diminishing returns. They also did not incorporate specific
levels of education in their respective econometric models. This study tries to bridge this gap.
The study is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the literature review. Section 3 describes the
data and presents the explanation of the estimation results, which contribute a deeper understanding
of how education affects income inequality in Asian developing countries. Section 4 concludes the
study with policy implications.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT