Economics and the Interpretation and Application of U.S. and E.U. Antitrust Law

AuthorRichard S. Markovits
Published date01 March 2016
DOI10.1177/0003603X15625126
Date01 March 2016
Article
Economics and the Interpretation
and Application of U.S. and E.U.
Antitrust Law: A Summary
Richard S. Markovits*
Abstract
Part 1 (1) articulates and explains (A) the specific-anticompetitive-intent test of illegality that the study
claims is promulgated by the Sherman Act, the object-branch of the test of illegality promulgated by
Article 101(1) of the Treaty of Lisbon, and the exclusionary-abuse branch of the test of illegality
promulgated by Article 102 of the Treaty of Lisbon; and (B) the lessening-competition test of
illegality that the study claims is promulgated by the Clayton Act, the effect-branch of the test of
illegality promulgated by Article 101(1) of the Treaty of Lisbon, and the European Merger Control
Regulation; and (2) attempts to justify the study’s claims that its operationalizations of those tests of
illegality are correct as a matter of law. Part 2 (1) articulates the study’s definition of the concept
of ‘‘the impact of a choice on economic efficiency,’’ (2) defines three categories of organizational
allocative (economic) efficiencies the study distinguishes and explains why the fact that conduct
generates any of these categories of organizational economic efficiency favors its legality under U.S. or
E.U. antitrust law, and (3) defines the other categories of economic inefficiency the study identifies and
explains why the impact of business conduct on the magnitudes of these categories of economic
inefficiency in the society in question is irrelevant to its legality under U.S. or E.U. antitrust law. Part 3
then (1) summarizes the study’s argument for its conclusion that definitions of both classical economic
markets and antitrust markets are inevitably arbitrary not just at their periphery but at their core,
(2) summarizes the study’s discussion of the concept of a firm’s dominance or economic (market)
power and its explanation of why a firm’s economic power could not be inferred from its market share
even if markets could be defined nonarbitrarily, (3) outlines the conceptual systems the study develops
and uses to analyze the competitiveness of prices and the impact of conduct on the intensity of price
competition respectively in individualized-pricing and across-the-board-pricing contexts, and (4)
articulates the study’s definitions of (A) the concept of quality-or-variety-increasing-investment
competition and (B) the concepts it uses to analyze the impact of conduct on such competition.
Part 4 outlines the most salient points the study makes about (1) coordinated conduct and oligopolistic
pricing, (2) predatory pricing and predatory investments, (3) horizontal mergers and acquisitions,
(4) conglomerate mergers, and (5) various pricing-techniques, contract-clause and sales-policy sur-
rogates for vertical integration, and vertical mergers and acquisitions. The Conclusion describes
an important part of the policy-sequel to this antitrust-law study that I have contracted to publish.
*The University of Texas at Austin, Austin, TX, USA
Corresponding Author:
Richard S. Markovits, The University of Texas at Austin, Austin, TX 78705, USA.
Email: rmarkovits@law.utexas.edu
The Antitrust Bulletin
2016, Vol. 61(1) 3-83
ªThe Author(s) 2016
Reprints and permission:
sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0003603X15625126
abx.sagepub.com
In particular, the Conclusion outlines the protocol that that sequel will use to analyze the economic
efficiency of any exemplar of any category of antitrust-law-covered conduct or of any policy-responses
to such conduct.
Keywords
allocative (economic) efficiency, conglomerate mergers, efficiency defense, essential-facilities doctrine,
foreclosure, General Theory of Second Best, horizontal mergers, interbrand competition, intrabrand
competition, joint ventures, long-term full-requirements contracts, long-term total-output-supply
contracts, market definition, market dominance, market power, market share, oligopolistic conduct,
oligopolistic pricing, predatory conduct, predatory investments, predatory price-squeezes, predatory
pricing, qualitative-substantiality test, quantitative-substantiality test, reciprocity agreements, resale
price maintenance, single-brand exclusive dealerships, toe-hold mergers (and toe-hold-merger
doctrine), vertical customer-allocation clauses, vertical mergers, vertical territorial restraints
This special issue of The Antitrust Bulletin is devoted to my two-volume study Economics and the
Interpretation and Application of U.S. and E.U. Antitrust Law.
1
This law-study has a not-yet-published
policy-study sequel entitled The Welfare Economics of Antitrust Policy and U.S. and E.U. Antitrust
Law: A Second-Best-Theory-Based Economic-Efficiency Analysis.
2
Each of the contributions to this special issue focuses on one of the topics the law-study addresses.
Although several refer to some elements of one or more of the conceptual schemes the law-study
develops and uses to address various antitrust-law issues, none gives a comprehensive account of any
of these schemes. The eight contributions in this issue also do not cover the law-study’s analyses of the
antitrust legality of many categories of business conduct; many of its critiques of conventional eco-
nomic concepts, theories, and conclusions; and many of its critiques of the antitrust-law-related
‘‘theories’’ advanced by, analytic protocols used by, and legal doctrines promulgated by U.S. and
European Union (E.U.) courts and U.S. and E.U. antitrust-enforcement authorities. This fact is not
surprising: the two volumes of the law-study total more than 1,400 pages. The four parts of this article
attempt both to fill in these gaps and to state the law-study’s positions on the various questions that the
other contributions to this special issue examine by providing, respectively, (1) statements of the law-
study’s conclusions about the tests of illegality and prima facie illegality that U.S. antitrust law and
E.U. competition law respectively promulgate and about the ‘‘efficiency-defenses’’ these two bodies of
law respectively recognize; (2) a definition of the concept of ‘‘the impact of a choice on economic
efficiency,’’ a list of the various categories of economic inefficiency an economy can contain, and an
account of the kinds of efficiencies and reductions in economic inefficiency that do and do not favor
the legality of conduct under U.S. and E.U. antitrust law; (3) accounts of (A) the law-study’s positions
on the concepts of classical-economic markets, antitrust markets, a firm’s economic (market) power,
and a firm’s (market) dominance and (B) the two novel conceptual schemes the law-study develops to
analyze, respectively, price-comp etition-related issues and quality- and-variety-competition-related
issues; and (4) summaries of the most original and/or salient points the law-study makes about various
categories of business conduct covered by U.S. and/or E.U. antitrust law. The article’s conclusion
1. The two volumes of ECONOMICS AND THE INTERPRETATION AND APPLICATION OF U.S. AND E.U. ANTITRUST LAW were published by
Springer in 2014. The subtitle of Vol. I is BASIC CONCEPTS AND ECONOMICS-BASED LEGAL ANALYSES OF OLIGOPOLISTIC AND
PREDATORY CONDUCT. Vol. I will be cited hereinafter as MARKOVITS,ECONOMICS OF ANTITRUST LAW I. The subtitle of Vol. II is
ECONOMICS-BASED LEGAL ANALYSES OF MERGERS,VERTICAL PRACTICES,AND JOINT VENTURES. It will be cited hereinafter as
MARKOVITS,ECONOMICS OF ANTITRUST LAW II.
2. This policy-study will also be published by Springer, hopefully in 2017.
4The Antitrust Bulletin 61(1)
provides a brief summary of the policy-sequel to the law-study on which this special issue of The
Antitrust Bulletin focuses.
1. The Conduct-Coverage of, Tests of Illegality or Prima Facie Illegality
Promulgated by, and Efficiency-Defenses Recognized by the U.S.
Antitrust Statutes, the E.U. Treaty’s Competition-Law Provisions, and
the European Commission’s (EC’s) Antitrust Regulations
A. The Conduct-Coverage of and Tests of Illegality or Prima Facie Illegality Promulgated by
U.S. and E.U. Antitrust Law
(1) The conduct-coverage of and formal statements of the tests of illegality promulgated by U.S. and E.U.
antitrust law. The U.S. Sherman Act
3
(which covers all types of business conduct other than natural
oligopolistic conduct and any unsuccessful att empt to enter into a contract in restraint of trade
4
)
prohibits agreements in restraint of trade (Section 1) and monopolization and attempts to monopolize
(Section 2). The U.S. Clayton Act
5
(whose Section 2 covers ‘‘price discrimination’’ as defined by the
statute;
6
whose Section 3 covers single-brand exclusive dealerships, full-requirements contracts, and
total-output-supply contracts; and whose Section 7 covers mergers and acquisitions) prohibits the
behavior it covers if that conduct is requisitely likely to or did lessen competition. The Federal Trade
3. 26 Stat. 209 (1890) (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. Sections 1-11) (hereinafter Sherman Act).
4. Natural oligopolistic conduct is conduct whose ex ante perpetrator-perceived profitability was critically affected by the
perpetrator’s belief that its rivals’ responses would or might be influenced by their belief that it would have the opportunity to
react to their responses and would find it inherently profitable to react to any undercutting or undermining response that they
would otherwise find profitable in one or more ways that would render those responses unprofitable for them. The law-study
uses the expression ‘‘undercuttingresponse’’ to refer to a response to an individualized oligopolistic price that would render it
unprofitable and the expression ‘‘underminingresponse’’ to refer to a response to an across-the-board oligopolistic price that
would render it unprofitable. For the referents of ‘‘individualizedprice’’ and ‘‘across-the-board price,’’see Part 3C infra. The
Sherman Act does not cover natural oligopolistic conduct because such conduct involves neither the making of an
anticompetitive agreement nor the making and carrying out of an anticompetitive threat or promise. My contestable
conclusion that the Sherman Act also does not cover any unsuccessful attempt to enter into an anticompetitive agreement
(an agreement in restraint of tr ade) reflects three facts: (1) t he section of the Sherman Act (Sec tion 1) that prohibits
agreements in restraint of trade does not explicitly prohibit unsuccessful attempts to form agreements in restraint of trade;
(2) the laws of the U.S. central government do not contain a general attempt statute (i.e., a statute that declares illegal any
unsuccessful attempt to commit an act that would be illegal if successfully completed); and (3) the U.S. courts have
consistently refused to read attempt provisions into statutes that do not contain them. I think that these facts imply that it
would be incorrect as a matter of law for U.S. courts either to read an attempt provision into Section 1 or to classify an
unsuccessful attempt to enter into an anticompetitive agreement to be an ‘‘attempt to monopolize’’ (which is prohibited by
Section 2). I should add that, for constitutional reasons, the Sherman Act should be given a so-called ‘‘saving construction’’
under which it would also be deemed not to cover any attempt (whether successful or not) by an individual actor to secure a
legislative, administrative, or judicial decision that would reduce the absolute attractiveness of the best offer(s) against which
it would have to compete in some way that would reduce economic efficiency in an otherwise-Pareto-perfect economy (see
n.10 infra) or any agreement by two or more actors to cooperate in securing such a government decision so long as the
conduct in question did not violate an appropriate criterion of fair play.
5. 38 Stat. 730 (1914) (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. Sections 12-27) (hereinafter Clayton Act).
6. The Clayton Act defines ‘‘price discrimination’’to be the requisitely-contemporaneous charging of different prices for the
same commodity to different buyers. In the Clayton Act’s terminology, a seller’s charging different prices to different buyers
is still called ‘‘price discrimination’’when the differences in prices reflect differences in the marginal(or incremental) costs
the relevant seller must incur to supply the buyers in question. According to the (superior) standard economics definition,
pricing that the Clayton Act would denominate ‘‘cost-justified price discrimination’’is not price discrimination at all. On the
standard economics definition, a seller would also be said to have practiced price discrimination if it charged different buyers
the same price despite the fact that it had to incur different marginal (or incremental) costs to supply them. On the Clayton
Act’s definition, the latter seller’s pricing would not involve ‘‘price discrimination.’’
Markovits 5

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT