Economic Principles for Medicare Reform

AuthorAmitabh Chandra,Craig Garthwaite
Date01 November 2019
DOI10.1177/0002716219885582
Published date01 November 2019
Subject MatterSocial Insurance
ANNALS, AAPSS, 686, November 2019 63
DOI: 10.1177/0002716219885582
Economic
Principles for
Medicare
Reform
By
AMITABH CHANDRA
and
CRAIG GARTHWAITE
885582ANN THE ANNALS OF THE AMERICAN ACADEMYECONOMIC PRINCIPLES FOR MEDICARE REFORM
research-article2019
In this article, we develop an economic framework for
Medicare reform that highlights trade-offs that reform
proposals should grapple with, but often ignore. Central
to our argument is a tension in administratively set
prices, which may improve short-term efficiency but do
so at the expense of dynamic efficiency (slowing inno-
vations in new treatments). The smaller the Medicare
program is relative to the commercial market, the less
important this is; but in a world where there are no
market prices or the private sector is very small, the
task of setting prices that are dynamically correct
becomes more complex. Reforming Medicare should
focus on greater incentives to increase competition
between Medicare Advantage plans, which necessitates
a role for government in ensuring competition; pre-
mium support; less use of regulated prices; and less
appetite for countless “pay for performance” schemes.
We apply this framework to evaluate Medicare for All
proposals.
Keywords: Medicare; value-based care; health care
reform; markets in health care
While the U.S. health care sector is often
described as a private, market-based sys-
tem, the government now controls more than
60 percent of spending (Martin et al. 2018).
Public insurers provide insurance to several
groups, including the elderly, the indigent, and
Amitabh Chandra is a professor at Harvard Business
School and a professor at the Harvard Kennedy School
of Government. He is a member of the Congressional
Budget Office’s (CBO) Panel of Health Advisors and is
a research associate at the National Bureau of Economic
Research (NBER).
Craig Garthwaite is a professor at the Kellogg School of
Management at Northwestern University, the director
of the Program on Healthcare at Kellogg (HCAK), and
a research associate at NBER.
NOTE: We are grateful to Jim Ziliak, Robert Moffit,
and conference participants for very helpful comments.
Correspondence: Amitabh_Chandra@Harvard.EDU
64 THE ANNALS OF THE AMERICAN ACADEMY
the disabled. Of all insurers in the United States, Medicare—which provides
health insurance for the elderly and a subset of the disabled population—is the
largest in terms of spending and is expected to grow even more in coming years
as a result of changing demographics. Given this breadth of coverage, Medicare’s
current coverage decisions and operations, as well as reforms to the program’s
structure, will likely have meaningful market-wide effects.
Medicare reform is important for a number of reasons. First, the demograph-
ics of the baby-boomers means Medicare enrollment is growing rapidly. This
enrollment growth is important as we consider reform, because it creates a politi-
cal constituency that will both demand improvements to the existing program
and push back against any reforms that are seen to decrease the generosity of
existing benefits—even if those reforms increase net social benefits (the net ben-
efit to patients and producers of health care, including the net benefit to
taxpayers).1
Second, even after the implementation of the Affordable Care Act (ACA), a
meaningful fraction of the U.S. population remains without health insurance
coverage (at the time of this writing, the percentage of uninsured hovers at 13
percent of the population, up from 10.9 percent in November 2016 [Witters
2019]). In addition, health care costs for even those who are insured are quite
high, and many individuals are in plans with high cost sharing relative to their
income, which leaves them underinsured to the financial risk of a health shock.
Many see the relative success of the existing Medicare program in providing
broad coverage to the elderly and want to expand it to others. Often described as
“Medicare for All,” these various policy proposals range from allowing progres-
sively younger individuals to purchase Medicare coverage to the expansion of the
existing Medicare program to serve as a single-payer system for the entirety of
the U.S. population.2 These proposals are popular, but popularity does not mean
that the hard work of grappling with the underlying trade-offs has been started,
let alone achieved.
Third, despite the ostensible “dual mandate” of the ACA to both increase
coverage and control costs, health care costs in the United States continue to
grow, albeit at a slower rate than in the past (Chandra, Holmes, and Skinner
2013). Concerns about rising costs and a lack of universal coverage has pushed
policy-makers to call for an expanded role for the Medicare system because of
the belief that a government-run program can be more administratively efficient
than a complex web of private firms offering coverage. In addition, some sup-
porters of such reforms believe a system of administratively set prices will be less
expensive, because these prices will be below those determined by a market
transaction. Other constituents, who are interested in the debt and tax ramifica-
tions of such a large health care program financed by the federal government,
want to reform the program accordingly. Still other reformers do not want to
shrink Medicare per se but believe it can be made more efficient—which
increases its sustainability and reduces the extent to which this program may be
crowding out other public spending priorities.
Finally, the last major changes to Medicare occurred in 2003 with the
Medicare Modernization Act (which introduced Medicare Advantage [MA]) and

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT