Economic Integration, Monopoly Power and Productivity Growth without Scale Effects

Date01 February 2016
AuthorColin Davis,Ken‐ichi Hashimoto
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12200
Published date01 February 2016
Economic Integration, Monopoly Power and
Productivity Growth without Scale Effects
Colin Davis and Ken-ichi Hashimoto*
Abstract
This paper considers how monopoly power affects the relationship between economic integration and eco-
nomic growth that is not biased by a scale effect. In a two-country model of trade, productivity growth is
generated by firm-level investment in process innovation, and the location of economic activity is deter-
mined by relative market size, trade costs and imperfect knowledge diffusion. Equilibrium features the
partial concentration of manufacturing and the full concentration of innovation in the larger country.
Increased economic integration raises the concentration of manufacturing in the larger country, and when
monopoly power is strong, leads to decreased product variety, accelerated productivity growth and greater
national welfare. With weak monopoly power, however, it raises product variety and dampens productivity
growth, but may benefit or hurt welfare.
1. Introduction
The last several decades have witnessed a dramatic trend towards economic integra-
tion at local, regional and national levels as the costs of transporting information and
goods have declined. In East Asia, falling communication and transport costs (Dee,
2007) and unilateral tariff-cutting (Baldwin, 2008) have lead to greater integration
between national economies, with a rise in the share of intra-regional manufacturing
trade from 36% in 1986 to 55% in 2006 (Athukorala and Kohpaiboon, 2010). This
improved regional integration has coincided with, and arguably been the impetus for,
shifts in economic activity towards the concentration of industry in specific geographic
locations (He, 2009). Indeed, Gill and Kharas (2007) estimate that 75% of annual
output is now produced in cities in East Asia, and Crescenzi et al. (2012) find that
innovation activity is even more geographically concentrated than manufacturing.
While casual observation suggests a causal relationship between regional integra-
tion and industry concentration in East Asia, the consequences for economic growth
are less clear. The theoretical conclusions of the new economic geography (NEG) lit-
erature tend to predict a positive relationship between industry concentration and
economic growth (Baldwin and Martin, 2004), but the empirical evidence is generally
mixed. Abdel-Rahman et al. (2006) report a negative relationship between
urbananization and economic growth for a sample of developing countries, however,
Brülhart and Sbergami (2009) conclude that the relationship between growth and
industry concentration depends on the level of economic development. In China,
positive effects of industry concentration are observed for labor productivity (Chen,
* Davis: The Institute for the Liberal Arts, Doshisha University, Karasuma-Higashi-iru, Imadegawa-dori,
Kamigyo, Kyoto, Japan, 602-8580. Tel: +81-75-251-4971; E-mail: cdavis@mail.doshisha.ac.jp. Hashimoto:
Graduate School of Economics, Kobe University, 2-1 Rokkodai, Nada, Kobe, Japan. The authors are
grateful for helpful comments from an anonymous referee, Tatsuro Iwaisako, Nobuaki Hamaguchi, and
participants of ETSG 2014. They acknowledge financial support from JSPS through a Grant-in-Aid for Sci-
entific Research (C) and a Grant-in-Aid for Young Scientists (B). All remaining errors are those of the
authors.
Review of Development Economics, 20(1), 152–163, 2016
DOI:10.1111/rode.12200
©2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT