Earnings management and agency costs: Is China different?

Published date01 January 2021
AuthorYimei Man
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/jcaf.22481
Date01 January 2021
J Corp Acct Fin. 2021;32:13–30. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jcaf © 2020 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. 13
BLIND PEER REVIEW
Earnings management and agency costs: Is China different?
Yimei Man
Department of Accountancy and Finance,
University of Otago Business School,
Otago, New Zealand
Correspondence
Yimei Man, Department of Accountancy
and Finance, University of Otago Business
School, Otago, New Zealand.
Email: yimei.man@otago.ac.nz
Abstract
In this article, we investigate the link between agency costs (AC) and earnings
management (EM) in China. We find a significant and positive relationship
between AC and EM based on the static model that suggests opportunistic EM
in China. However, we find an insignificant relationship between AC and EM
when we use the dynamic model that takes into account the endogeneity issue.
Therefore, our results provide further support to the growing literature on the
concerns of endogeneity issues in corporate governance studies, since failing to
take these into account can lead to spurious results.
KEYWORDS
agency costs, earnings management, corporate governance
1|INTRODUCTION
Earnings management (EM) is defined as active manip-
ulation of accounting results for the purpose of creating
an altered impression of business performance
(Mulford & Comiskey, 2002, p. 59). EM activities are
often motivated by management incentives, such as the
ownership and management conflict (i.e., agency con-
flict). Agency costs (AC) occur in an effort to resolve
agency conflicts and better align the interests of owner-
ship and management. A high level of AC indicates inef-
ficient monitoring activities and weak corporate
governance (CG) (Jensen & Meckling, 1976; Shleifer &
Vishny, 1997). Based on agency theory, Jiraporn
et al. (2008) posit that agency conflicts could induce man-
agers to exploit the flexibility in accounting policies to
manage earnings, and they find that EM mitigates AC in
the US market.
In this article, we examine the AC/EM nexus in
China. We choose China for four reasons. First, the legal
environment in China is relatively underdeveloped com-
pared with the US and other developed countries (Chen
et al., 2006). It is important to study how the AC/EM
nexus differs in countries with a relatively underdevel-
oped legal environment, such as China, considering that
agency problems are more severe in emerging economies
than the developed economies due to weak legal protec-
tion and other governance mechanisms (La Porta
et al., 1998; La Porta et al., 2002).
Second, there is strong evidence of EM (Chen &
Yuan, 2004; Haw et al., 2005) and AC (Li et al., 2011; Li
et al., 2014) among Chinese firms. However, there is no
empirical evidence available on the relationship between
EM and AC in China. Therefore, China provides us with
an out-of-sample opportunity to examine whether
Jiraporn et al.'s (2008) findings that EM mitigates AC in
the US market can be generalized to China.
Third, the Communist Party has a strong influence
on CG in China. For example, the majority shareholder
of listed companies in China is often the state; China's
company law requires Chinese companies to establish a
supervisory board that typically includes officials from
the company's internal Communist Party committee.
Therefore, the agency problem is worsened in China
because of the weak ability of principals (i.e., Chinese cit-
izens) to monitor the performance of the agent. This cre-
ates an opportunity for managers (i.e., Communist Party
officials) to pursue their own interests instead of those of
the principals.
Finally, China is important as the largest emerging
economy and the largest recipient of foreign direct invest-
ment among developing countries (United Nations
Received: 15 April 2020 Revised: 2 November 2020 Accepted: 17 November 2020
DOI: 10.1002/jcaf.22481
J Corp Acct Fin. 2020;118. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jcaf © 2020 Wiley Periodicals LLC 1
MAN14
structure of the market. Firms with little available infor-
mation may experience higher costs of capital. The
impact of information in influencing the costs of capital
are indicated by several studies (Botosan, 1997;
Christensen, de la Rosa, & Feltham, 2010; Easley &
O'hara, 2004; Feltham, Robb, & Zhang, 2007; Huang
& Kang, 2018; Hughes, Liu, & Liu, 2007; Lambert,
Leuz, & Verrecchia, 2012; Perera & Nimal, 2017). For
instance, the rational expectations model explains the
relationship between private information and the costs of
capital. Besides, Ahn, Horenstein, and Wang (2018)
explain the effects of asymmetric information on the
asset equilibrium price.
Some researchers have shown the role of private
information in dictating the prices of assets. Bai, Bali,
and Wen (2019) for instance build on the classic analysis
of rational expectation to elucidate the role of asymmetric
information on asset value. They find that the presence
of agents in transactions affects the riskreturn tradeoffs
thus affecting the portfolios held by the informed and
uninformed investors. Besides, Dow and Gorton (1995)
explains that informed investors may profit from their
information while the uninformed investors' loss due to
lack of information. The main set back of this setback is
that it does not consider the costs of capital in its
assumption.
Another set of literature considers the role of incom-
plete information and symmetric information. Particu-
larly, Amihud (2018) investigates the effects of capital
market equilibriums in situations where the agents lack
some information about certain assets in the market. In
this model, agents who have information on the existence
of certain assets may decide on the distribution of
returns. However, the information is incomplete because
not all agents have knowledge of such information. The
analysis by Amihud shows that the value of an organiza-
tion's assets may be lower due to the existence of incom-
plete information. However, in normal circumstances,
some investors may have more knowledge about returns
than others. Besides, all the investors know about the
existence of every asset in the market through the infor-
mation that may be asymmetric.
Lastly, information disclosure by a firm may affect
the costs of capital because disclosure of private informa-
tion turns it into public information (Deno, Loy, &
Homburg, 2019). The presence of public information
means that each investor has access to information
regarding investments. Since the process of producing
information is costly, individuals ought to spend consid-
erable resources to collect information. Public informa-
tion increases the value of assets and capital since the
information lowers the risks of uninformed investors to
hold assets (Gârleanu & Pedersen, 2018). Diamond and
Verrecchia (1991) state that disclosure of information can
either improve or worsen liquidity depending on the
decisions by holders of information. The accessibility of
public information affects the riskiness or profitability of
an investment. Other researchers such as Kandelousi,
Alifiah, and Karimiyan (2016) incorporate other impor-
tant elements of information sharing such as insiders and
strategic disclosure issues.
2.2 |Cost of capital
The cost of capital is the amount expected by investors
after they have offered the capital required by a business.
Mostly, the sources of capital in a firm comprises of
investors who purchase stocks and the bondholders who
offer loans to an organization (Hertig, 2019). Conse-
quently, companies are expected to make returns that
ensure that both investors and the debt holders get
expected returns on investments. The cost of capital may
entail the mechanical calculations by financial people,
which is then used by management to come up with a
hurdle or discount rate. Businesses have to exceed the
hurdle rate in justifying investments (Anderson, Byers, &
Groth, 2000).
Mostly, the costs of capital may be slightly under the
required rate of return (McNulty, Yeh, Schulze, &
Lubatkin, 2002). The costs of capital in a firm are used to
determine the soundness of an investment. Besides,
investors use the costs of capital to assess the riskiness of
an investment. Companies only choose to commit their
finances in projects whose return exceeds the costs of
capital. As such, managers should always look for invest-
ments that exceed the costs of capital in an individual
organization (Easley, O'Hara, & Yang, 2016). Conversely,
investors look at the beta or volatility of investments to
determine whether an investment is worthwhile. The
costs of capital determine the corporate strategies and the
ability of an organization to compete in the future. Busi-
nesses may use the costs of capital to make capital
budgeting decisions to offer a strategic advantage to a
firm in the short run.
Though investment opportunities' in organizations
differ, the techniques of evaluating the financial returns
are similar. However, the value of investments made an
organization depend on the profitability of the invest-
ment portfolio undertaken by a firm. The expectations
about an investment determine whether a company will
make positive or negative returns. The costs of capital
influence the hurdle rate and the capital structure in a
firm. Also, the costs of capital may determine the opera-
tions of a firm that in turn determine the profitability
(Scott & Pascoe, 1984). According to Kandelousi
TÜREGÜN 3
structure of the market. Firms with little available infor-
mation may experience higher costs of capital. The
impact of information in influencing the costs of capital
are indicated by several studies (Botosan, 1997;
Christensen, de la Rosa, & Feltham, 2010; Easley &
O'hara, 2004; Feltham, Robb, & Zhang, 2007; Huang
& Kang, 2018; Hughes, Liu, & Liu, 2007; Lambert,
Leuz, & Verrecchia, 2012; Perera & Nimal, 2017). For
instance, the rational expectations model explains the
relationship between private information and the costs of
capital. Besides, Ahn, Horenstein, and Wang (2018)
explain the effects of asymmetric information on the
asset equilibrium price.
Some researchers have shown the role of private
information in dictating the prices of assets. Bai, Bali,
and Wen (2019) for instance build on the classic analysis
of rational expectation to elucidate the role of asymmetric
information on asset value. They find that the presence
of agents in transactions affects the riskreturn tradeoffs
thus affecting the portfolios held by the informed and
uninformed investors. Besides, Dow and Gorton (1995)
explains that informed investors may profit from their
information while the uninformed investors' loss due to
lack of information. The main set back of this setback is
that it does not consider the costs of capital in its
assumption.
Another set of literature considers the role of incom-
plete information and symmetric information. Particu-
larly, Amihud (2018) investigates the effects of capital
market equilibriums in situations where the agents lack
some information about certain assets in the market. In
this model, agents who have information on the existence
of certain assets may decide on the distribution of
returns. However, the information is incomplete because
not all agents have knowledge of such information. The
analysis by Amihud shows that the value of an organiza-
tion's assets may be lower due to the existence of incom-
plete information. However, in normal circumstances,
some investors may have more knowledge about returns
than others. Besides, all the investors know about the
existence of every asset in the market through the infor-
mation that may be asymmetric.
Lastly, information disclosure by a firm may affect
the costs of capital because disclosure of private informa-
tion turns it into public information (Deno, Loy, &
Homburg, 2019). The presence of public information
means that each investor has access to information
regarding investments. Since the process of producing
information is costly, individuals ought to spend consid-
erable resources to collect information. Public informa-
tion increases the value of assets and capital since the
information lowers the risks of uninformed investors to
hold assets (Gârleanu & Pedersen, 2018). Diamond and
Verrecchia (1991) state that disclosure of information can
either improve or worsen liquidity depending on the
decisions by holders of information. The accessibility of
public information affects the riskiness or profitability of
an investment. Other researchers such as Kandelousi,
Alifiah, and Karimiyan (2016) incorporate other impor-
tant elements of information sharing such as insiders and
strategic disclosure issues.
2.2 |Cost of capital
The cost of capital is the amount expected by investors
after they have offered the capital required by a business.
Mostly, the sources of capital in a firm comprises of
investors who purchase stocks and the bondholders who
offer loans to an organization (Hertig, 2019). Conse-
quently, companies are expected to make returns that
ensure that both investors and the debt holders get
expected returns on investments. The cost of capital may
entail the mechanical calculations by financial people,
which is then used by management to come up with a
hurdle or discount rate. Businesses have to exceed the
hurdle rate in justifying investments (Anderson, Byers, &
Groth, 2000).
Mostly, the costs of capital may be slightly under the
required rate of return (McNulty, Yeh, Schulze, &
Lubatkin, 2002). The costs of capital in a firm are used to
determine the soundness of an investment. Besides,
investors use the costs of capital to assess the riskiness of
an investment. Companies only choose to commit their
finances in projects whose return exceeds the costs of
capital. As such, managers should always look for invest-
ments that exceed the costs of capital in an individual
organization (Easley, O'Hara, & Yang, 2016). Conversely,
investors look at the beta or volatility of investments to
determine whether an investment is worthwhile. The
costs of capital determine the corporate strategies and the
ability of an organization to compete in the future. Busi-
nesses may use the costs of capital to make capital
budgeting decisions to offer a strategic advantage to a
firm in the short run.
Though investment opportunities' in organizations
differ, the techniques of evaluating the financial returns
are similar. However, the value of investments made an
organization depend on the profitability of the invest-
ment portfolio undertaken by a firm. The expectations
about an investment determine whether a company will
make positive or negative returns. The costs of capital
influence the hurdle rate and the capital structure in a
firm. Also, the costs of capital may determine the opera-
tions of a firm that in turn determine the profitability
(Scott & Pascoe, 1984). According to Kandelousi
TÜREGÜN 3
Conference on Trade and Development, 2017). The estab-
lishment of the Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank
(AIIB) and implementation of the Belt and Road Initia-
tive have further boosted the interests of foreign inves-
tors, financial institutions, multinational companies, and
academics in the Chinese economy.
To examine the AC/EM relationship, we employ
static and dynamic modeling frameworks. The prevalent
endogeneity issue in CG studies often leads to spurious
results (Wintoki et al., 2012). Based on the static model,
we find that EM increases AC. However, the two-step
system generalized method of moments (GMM) dynamic
model that takes into account the dynamic nature of cor-
porate governance and other sources of endogeneity
(e.g., simultaneity, omitted variable, measurement error)
casts doubts on the causal relationship between AC
and EM.
We contribute to the corporate governance literature
in two ways. First, we provide further support to the
growing literature that has raised concerns on the endo-
geneity issue in CG studies (Pham et al., 2011; Schultz
et al., 2010; Wintoki et al., 2012), since our results indi-
cate that failing to take endogeneity issues into account
can lead to spurious results. Second, we extend the litera-
ture beyond developed markets by providing the first
empirical evidence on the role of EM in agency conflicts
in China.
The remainder of the article is organized as follows:
Section 2 provides the relevant literature on the relation-
ship between AC and EM and discusses the endogeneity
issue in CG studies; Section 3 describes data and
methods; Section 4 provides empirical results; and Sec-
tion 5 concludes the article.
2|LITERATURE REVIEW
2.1 |Agency costs and earnings
management
Research on EM originated in the US market and dates
back to the 1980s. For example, Healy (1985) finds that
managers choose accounting procedures selectively in
order to maximize the value of their compensation or
bonus. EM activities are found prior to the period of a
management buyout (Perry & Williams, 1994) and the
period of an equity offering (Teoh et al., 1998a; Teoh
et al., 1998b) to fit the stock market's purposes. EM activi-
ties are also found prevalent in the Chinese companies
where managers manage earnings to meet certain regula-
tory benchmarks and accounting thresholds to obtain
permission to issue shares (Chen & Yuan, 2004; Haw
et al., 2005; Kao et al., 2009).
Several theories explain the rationale for
EM. According to agency theory, managers are motivated
to undertake EM and resolve agency problems. Hill and
Jones (1992) extend agency theory to say that managers
act as the agent for all the interest-related parties not only
for the owners, and are therefore motivated to undertake
EM activities to coordinate the nexus of various stake-
holders. According to legitimacy theory, managers man-
age earnings to meet the expectation of the internal
stakeholder and the public to acquire and maintain the
legitimacy of the firm (Djelic, 2001; Guler et al., 2002;
Sun et al., 2010).
AC occurs through the separation between and the
divergence of ownership and management (Jensen &
Meckling, 1976). The managers (i.e., agents) tend to be
interested in pursuing their objectives, instead of always
maximizing the benefits of the shareholders
(i.e., principals). AC has been considered as one of the
fundamental problems in improving the corporate gover-
nance mechanism (Shleifer & Vishny, 1997). Even in the
advanced economies, such as the US market, where the
governance mechanism is extensively studied, there is
still ongoing debate on how to better align owner-
manager interests and to mitigate managerial expropria-
tion (Bates et al., 2009; Bebchuk et al., 2008; Harford
et al., 2012; Lazonick & O'sullivan, 2000).
Although China has borrowed the CG setups from
the developed market, only the form of CG has been
inherited not the substance (Backman, 1999). Unlike the
widespread shareholders in the developed market, the
ownership structure in Chinese listed companies is often
state-concentrated. Previous studies in developed markets
suggest that the managerial ownership may moderate
agency conflict (Ang et al., 2000; Singh & Davidson
III, 2003). However, owner management is not a panacea
for eliminating the agency problem (Schulze et al., 2001).
Especially in China, managers are rarely significant
shareholders in listed companies
1
(Jiang & Kim, 2015),
providing institutional roots for agency problems (Lin
et al., 2006; Xu et al., 2005).
Management's incentive connects AC with EM. The
practice of EM can bring reported earnings to the desired
level; hence, it is natural for the managers to engage in
EM to satisfy self-interest (Schipper, 1989; Scott, 1997).
The case for a nexus between AC and EM has been
strongly asserted in prior studies (Jiraporn et al., 2008;
Lambert, 1984). The advocates of beneficial EM argue
that EM can be used to add information value, reduce
information asymmetry, and mitigate AC (Arya
et al., 2003; Louis & Robinson, 2005; Warfield
et al., 1995). However, when managers undertake EM to
benefit themselves, EM can be used opportunistically to
deteriorate AC (Bergstresser & Philippon, 2006;
2MAN

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT