Dynamic Risk Management: Investment, Capital Structure, and Hedging in the Presence of Financial Frictions

Date01 June 2015
AuthorThomas‐Olivier Léautier,Diego Amaya,Geneviève Gauthier
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jori.12025
Published date01 June 2015
©2014 The Journal of Risk and Insurance. Vol.82, No. 2, 359–399 (2015).
DOI: 10.1111/jori.12025
Dynamic Risk Management: Investment, Capital
Structure, and Hedging in the Presence of
Financial Frictions
Diego Amaya
Genevi`
eve Gauthier
Thomas-Olivier L´
eautier
Abstract
This article develops a dynamic risk management model to determine a firm’s
optimal risk management strategy.This strategy has two elements. First, for
low-leverage values, the firm fully hedges its operating cash flow exposure,
due to the convexity of its cost of capital. When leverage exceeds a very high
threshold, the firm gambles for resurrection and stops hedging. Second, the
firm manages its capital structure through dividend distributions and in-
vestment. When leverage is low, the firm replaces depreciated assets, fully
invests in opportunities if they arise, and distribute dividends, all of these to-
gether to achieve its optimal capital structure. As leverage increases, the firm
stops paying dividends, while fully investing. After a certain leverage, the
firm also reduces investment until it stops investing completely. The model
predictions are consistent with empirical observations.
Introduction
Risk management is a critical issue for all firms. Over the last 15 years, many
financial and nonfinancial firms have adopted an integrated approach to measure
and manage all their risks, called enterprise risk management (ERM). The definition
of risk management is now broader; it includes not only derivatives usage, but also
the choice of capital structure, the constitution of cash reserves and lines of credit,
the structuring of the insurance portfolio, and sometimes operational policies (see,
Diego Amaya is in the Finance Department, Universit´
eduQu´
ebec `
a Montr´
eal (UQAM), Qu´
ebec,
Canada. Genevi`
eve Gauthier is in the Department of Management Sciences, HEC Montr´
eal,
and GERAD Qu´
ebec, Canada. Thomas-Olivier L´
eautier is at the ToulouseSchool of Economics
(IDEI-IAE-CRM), France. Diego Amaya can be contacted via e-mail: amaya.diego@uqam.ca.
Diego Amaya would like to thank FQRNT and IFM2for financial support. Genevi`
eve Gau-
thier would like to thank NSERC and IFM2for financial support. An earlier version of this
article was circulated under the title, “Coordinating Capital Structure With Risk Management
Policies.” We thank seminar participants at the Annual Conference on Risk Management and
Corporate Governance, the Annual Australasian Finance and Banking Conference, and the
Midwest Financial Association meetings for their comments on earlier versions of this article.
Any remaining inadequacies are ours alone.
359
360 The Journal of Risk and Insurance
e.g., Léautier, Rochet, and Villeneuve, 2007; Pettit, 2007; Hyot and Liebenberg, 2011;
Paape and Spekte, 2012 and the references they contain).
A rich academic literature (reviewed later in this section) has accompanied this cor-
porate interest in risk management. Numerous articles have identified fundamental
financial frictions that justify risk management (e.g., tax shield from debt, bankruptcy
and business disruption costs, costly external financing, asymmetry of information
between managers/insiders and investors/outsiders), and have derived the optimal
risk management strategy, given these frictions.
This article attempts to better relate corporate practice and finance theory of risk man-
agement. It proposes a reduced form model that represents what managers of large
publicly traded firms actually do. As reported by Graham and Harvey’s (2001) survey,
chief financial officers ( CFOs) are agnostic as to the origin of financial frictions. They
simply observe that the weighted average cost of capital (WACC)is a U-shaped func-
tion of the firm’s leverage ratio (Graham and Harvey, 2001; Cohen, 2004; Pettit, 2007,
pp. 110–111, 141–159). Takingthis observation as given, they make capital budgeting,
dividend distribution, and hedging decisions to maximize the expected net present
value (NPV) of the free cash flows, facing uncertainty about both future cash flows
and future investment opportunities, and the possibility of bankruptcy. This repre-
sentation of managerial decision-making cannot be derived from micro-foundations.
Yet, it provides valuable insights for it captures most of the real features of corpo-
rate decision-making; hence, the analysis’ predictions can be compared against actual
firms’ behavior, as captured by previous empirical studies.
This article first determines analytically the optimal risk management strategy, that
is, the mix of hedging, dividend distribution, refinancing, and investment policies.
Second, it illustrates the optimal strategy for a “representative” industrial firm, using
estimates of the main model parameters. Finally,it shows that the model’s predictions
are consistent with empirical observations.
The main result of this article is the optimal risk management strategy, which is
surprisingly simple. First, dividend distribution and investment jointly follow four
regimes (Proposition 1). For low leverage, the firm enjoys full financial flexibility: it fully
finances its investment needs and distributes dividends to reach its optimal leverage
ratio. For intermediate leverage, the firm faces financial tightness: it still fully finances
its investment needs but no longer distributes dividends, as leverage increases from
one period to the next. For higher leverage, the firm faces a financial constraint:itisno
longer able to fully finance its investment needs. The portion it finances is determined
to reach a target leverage, after which the marginal value of investing becomes nega-
tive. Finally, for high leverage, the firm faces financial hardship: it is no longer able to
finance any of its investment needs, not even depreciation.
Second, full hedging is optimal unless leverage gets higher than some threshold, in
which case gambling for resurrection becomes optimal (Proposition 2). These results
differ from previouswork (e.g., Bolton, Chen, and Wang, 2011; Rochet and Villeneuve,
2011), who find that when the firm’s cash reserve (or cash-to-capital ratio in Bolton et
al., 2011) is high enough, the firm becomes risk neutral and, since hedging is costly,
Dynamic Risk Management 361
stops hedging. In our model, the tax shield drives the concavity of the value function;
hence, the optimality of full hedging. By choosing leverage as the state variable, we
are able to capture the tax shield from debt, a real effect absent from Rochet and
Villeneuve (2011) and Bolton et al. (2011).
An essential finding of the analysis is that if the firm’s expected profitability is lower
than a threshold (function of the magnitude of its investment opportunity), the firm
does not exhaust the benefits of the tax shield; rather, it keeps an equity cushion
(Proposition 3): the optimal leverage target is lower than the static optimum that
minimizes the cost of capital.
The analysis enables us to estimate the value of hedging: a firm that fully hedges its
risk can increase its optimal leverage, which results in lower cost of capital, hence,
higher value.
The implications of the model are consistent with previously reported empirical find-
ings. First, Proposition 1 predicts that, ceteris paribus, dividend distribution decreases
when firms are less profitable on average or face higher investment opportunities,
which is confirmed by Fama and French (2002). Second, the importance of corporate
taxes in the decision to hedge (Proposition 2) is confirmed empirically by Graham
and Rogers (2002). Third, Graham (2000) reports that even profitable firms with low
expected cost of financial distress hold an equity cushion, consistent with our model
(Proposition 3). Finally, the numerical example developed in the article suggests the
value of hedging is around 5 percenton average, consistent with Allayanis and Weston
(2001).
As mentioned earlier, this article builds on a rich theoretical and empirical literature.
Most of the results hinge on the fact that the firm’s value is a concave function of
leverage with a unique maximum. In this model, the concavity of this function is
caused by the convexity of the expected return required by investors, itself motivated
by empirical considerations. Three families of theoretical models also produce value
functions of similar shape.
The first family of models develops the trade-off theory of capital structure (Leland,
1994, 1996; Leland and Toft, 1996): optimal capital structure trades-off the tax advan-
tage of debt against the direct and indirect bankruptcy costs. Since interest are tax
deductible, debt creates a tax shield. While there is no consensus on the appropriate
discount rate for the tax shield (Welch, 2008, pp. 504–507), all agree that the value of
the tax shield; hence, the value of the firm, increases with the leverage. On the other
hand, as leverage increases, so do the probability of bankruptcy and business disrup-
tion costs. In addition, firms may engage in risk-shifting behavior, choosing riskier
strategies that benefit shareholders at the expense of bondholders. Incorporating all
these effects, Leland (1996) derives the value of risky debt, the value of equity, and
the optimal capital structure and risk management strategy.
The second family of models relies on costly external financing. The interaction be-
tween costly external financing, underinvestment, and risk management was first
modeled in a two-period environment by Froot, Sharfstein, and Stein (1993) and Froot

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT