A Dynamic Model of Firm Valuation

Published date01 August 2018
AuthorNatalia Lazzati,Amilcar A. Menichini
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/fire.12164
Date01 August 2018
The Financial Review 53 (2018) 499–531
A Dynamic Model of Firm Valuation
Natalia Lazzati
University of California Santa Cruz
Amilcar A. Menichini
Graduate School of Business and Public Policy,Naval Postgraduate School
Abstract
Wepropose a dynamic version of the dividend discount model, solve it in closed form, and
assess its empirical validity. The valuationmethod is tractable and can be easily implemented.
We find that our model produces equity value forecasts that are very close to market prices,
and explains a large proportion of the observed variation in share prices. Moreover, we show
that a simple portfolio strategy based on the difference between market and estimated values
earns considerably positive returns. These returns cannot be simply explained either by the
Fama-French three-factor model (even after adding a momentum factor) or the Fama-French
five-factor model.
Keywords: firm valuation, dividend discount model, Gordon Growth Model, dynamic pro-
gramming
JEL Classifications: G31, G32
Corresponding author: Department of Economics, University of California Santa Cruz, 1156 High St.,
Santa Cruz, CA 95064; Phone: (831) 459-5697; Fax: (831) 459-5697; E-mail: nlazzati@ucsc.edu.
We thank the financial support from the Center for Analytical Finance (CAFIN) at UC Santa Cruz, as
well as the research assistance of Luka Kocic. We also thank the helpful comments from Srinivasan
Krishnamurthy,an anonymous referee, Scott Cederburg, Daniel Chi, Joseph Engelberg, Chris Lamoureux,
Charles M. C. Lee, Jun Liu, Timothy McQuade, YuriTserlukevich, Zafer Yuksel,and seminar participants
at U Arizona, UC Santa Cruz, and UMass Boston. Finally, we thank Ken French for making the data
publicly available.
C2018 The Eastern Finance Association 499
500 N. Lazzati and A. A. Menichini/The Financial Review 53 (2018) 499–531
1. Introduction
Wederive a dynamic model of the firm in closed form and show that it can be used
for actual firm valuation.To test its empirical validity,we price firms in COMPUSTAT
in the period 1980–2015 and evaluatethe results from three perspectives. First, we find
that the model produces consistent forecasts of stock prices in the sense that model
predicted values are very close to the actual market values, on average. Second,
we show that the model explains a large fraction (around 92%) of the variation
in current market prices. Third, we find that the temporary or short-run deviations
between market prices and model estimates can be economically exploited. Overall,
we believe these results suggest our model is a valuable pricing tool that may enhance
current approaches to firm valuation.
We use dynamic programming to develop a model of the firm in which the
latter chooses investment, labor, and how to finance its assets in every period. While
this type of model has been used extensively in corporate finance to explain firm
behavior, we introduce three fundamental features that make our model particu-
larly useful for asset pricing purposes. First, we invoke the two-fund separation
principle, which shows that, as long as we discount future cash flows with an appro-
priately risk-adjusted discount rate, we do not need to specify shareholders’ utility
functions in the valuation process beyond the assumptions discussed in Cass and
Stiglitz (1970). Second, we allow the firm to grow in the long run, which could be
interpreted as the firm facing a market size that increases over time, independent
of the short-term fluctuations generated by the business cycle. Third, we intro-
duce risky debt to our model and find an analytic solution, which, to the best of
our knowledge, is novel among existing discrete-time dynamic investment models
of the firm. In particular, debt in our model is protected by a positive net-worth
covenant and, in the event of bankruptcy, the firm pays the bankruptcy costs, is
reorganized under Chapter 11 of the U.S. Bankruptcy Code, and continues its op-
erations. This modeling strategy generates a debt behavior that is in line with the
empirical evidence. For instance, survey results from Graham and Harvey (2001)
suggest that most firms have a target leverage. Consistently, the firm in our model
chooses debt in every period following a target leverage that depends on its own
characteristics.
As mentioned above, an important advantage of our model regarding valuation
is that we solve it analytically. Closed-form equations are strongly preferred to
numerical approximations because the former yield extremely accurate values at very
low computing time. Indeed, a usual problem with the numerical solution of dynamic
programming models is the so-called Bellman’scurse of dimensionality. This problem
arises from the discretization of continuous state and decision variables, since the
computer time and space needed increase exponentially with the number of points
in the discretization (Rust, 1997, 2008). Thus, more accurate firm valuations imply
necessarily exponentially longer periods of computing time. In addition, explicit
solutions allow the user to estimate model parameters with ease.
N. Lazzati and A. A. Menichini/The Financial Review 53 (2018) 499–531 501
After presenting the firm model, we evaluate its actual pricing performance.
We first compute the ratio of the actual market prices to the values predicted by our
model and find that its mean value is around 1. This result means that our model
yields equity value estimates that are, on average, very close to market values. We
regress the market value of equity on the value estimated by our model and find that
we cannot reject the null hypothesis that the intercept is 0 and the slope is 1, which
suggests that our model produces unbiased estimates of stock prices. We also show
that our model predictions can explain a large fraction of the observed variability of
the stock prices. Specifically, the R2coefficient is around 92%. This outcome turns
out to be better than the results reported by related papers (described below), and
implies a strong linkage between model forecasts and market values over time. We
implement this last regression which includes fixed effects at the industry level and
find that, jointly they are not statistically different from zero with a p-value close to
0.67. Moreover, we run an analogous regression at the firm level and find that we
cannot reject the null hypothesis that the intercept is 0 and the slope is 1 for about
71% of the firms at the 5% significance level and for 83% of the firms at the 1%
significance level.
While we show that our estimates are very close to market values, we also
find temporary deviations between stock prices and model estimates. We implement
a simple spread strategy to test whether we can take economic advantage of these
deviations. The spread strategy consists in ranking firms based on their ratios of
market prices to model estimates, then forming quintiles based on those ratios, and
finally buying the firms in the lowest quintile and selling the firms in the highest
quintile. Our results show that this strategy earns, on average, around 20%, 34%,
41%, 44%, and 48% returns after one, two, three, four, and five years of portfolio
formation, respectively.We also study the returns of the spread strategy in the context
of the Fama-French three-factor model (Fama and French, 1993) and find a positive
alpha that is statistically different from zero. This means that the positive returns of
our spread strategy cannot be simply accounted for by these factors. Weobtain similar
results when we add a momentum factor to the Fama-French three-factor model and
when we employ the Fama-French five-factor model (Fama and French, 2015). As
benchmark, we calculate the returns of the spread strategy based on three well-
known financial ratios: market-to-book, price-earnings, and price-dividend. Based
on our model, we find that the spread strategy estimates consistently outperforms the
ones using these ratios.
To do the previous analyses, we estimate the structural parameters at the firm
level for all firms in our data set. In all our estimations, we perform a forward-looking
exercise in the sense that we use data available prior to the valuation period to make
out-of-sample predictions. Doing so is important because this procedure replicates
the situation a user would face when performing actual valuation.
This paper values public firms in COMPUSTAT. However,our valuation method
could also be implemented with firms for which market prices do not exist, as long
as financial statements are available for parameter estimation. These cases include,

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT