Dynamic limit pricing

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12176
AuthorFlavio Toxvaerd
Published date01 March 2017
Date01 March 2017
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.48, No. 1, Spring 2017
pp. 281–306
Dynamic limit pricing
Flavio Toxvaerd
I study a multiperiod model of limit pricing under one-sided incomplete information. I characterize
pooling and separating equilibria and their existence and determine when these involve limit
pricing. Forsome parameter constellations, the unique equilibrium surviving a D1 type refinement
involves immediate separation on monopoly prices. For others, there are limit price equilibria
surviving the refinement in which different types may initially pool and then (possibly) separate.
Separation involves setting prices such that the inefficient incumbent’s profits from mimicking
are negative. As the horizon increases or as firms become more patient, limit pricing becomes
increasingly difficult to sustain in equilibrium.
1. Introduction
Since Bain’s (1949) pioneering work, limit pricing has been a staple of industrial economics.
In a nutshell, limit pricing is the practice by which an incumbent firm (or cartel) deters potential
entry to an industry by pricing below the profit maximizing price level. Early workon the subject
took its cue from the casual observation that in some industries, firms price below the myopic
profit maximizing price level on a persistent basis. This observation lead to the notion that by
doing so, incumbent firms could somehow discourage potential entry which would otherwise
have occurred, in effect by sacrificing profits in the short run in return for a maintenance of the
monopoly position in the long run.
Bain (1949) noted that “[ . . . ] established sellers persistently or ‘in the long run’ forego
prices high enough to maximize the industry profit for fear of thereby attracting new entry to the
industry and thus reducing the demands for their outputs and their own profits.”
The present work revisits receivedwisdom on equilibrium limit pricing in dynamic contexts,
by way of a dynamic extension of a simple static model of one-sided incomplete information
University of Cambridge; fmot2@cam.ac.uk.
I thank YairTauman for constructive conversations and exchanges of ideas at an early stage of this project. I also thank
Heski Bar-Isaac, Jean-Pierre Benoit, Alex Gershkov,Paul Heidhues, GeorgeMailath, Joao Montez, Romans Pancs, In-Uck
Park, Patrick Rey,Charles Roddie, and seminar participants at the Hebrew University of Jerusalem, Universidad Torcuato
Di Tella, Universidad de San Andres, the University of Bonn, Universidad del CEMA, the University of Cambridge,
and the First London IO Day for useful comments. Next, I wish to thank participants at the following conferences
for feedback and comments: the Econometric Society European Meetings, Vienna (2006), the annual meetings of the
American Economic Association, Chicago (2007), the Royal Economic Society,Warwick (2008), the annual meetings of
the European Association for Research in Industrial Economics, Toulouse (2008), the Latin American Meetings of the
Econometric Society, Buenos Aires (2009), and the Conference on Research on Economic Theory and Econometrics,
Milos (2011). Last, I wish to thank the Editor and two anonymous referees for constructive suggestions that helped
improve this work.
C2017, The RAND Corporation. 281
282 / THE RAND JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
in the spirit of Milgrom and Roberts (1982). I demonstrate that although some aspects of the
standard (static) analysis may be preserved qualitatively when moving to dynamic contexts, the
quantitative results may radically differ. The analysis shows that when the horizon is sufficiently
long and the players sufficiently patient, limit pricing becomes infeasible altogether.
In this article, I analyze a model of limit pricing with one-sided incomplete information in
which a simple entry game is repeated as long as entry has not occurred. In this model, I identify
two distinct regimes, a monopoly price regime and a limit price regime. In the monopoly price
regime, limit price equilibria may existb ut all such equilibria are ruled out byusing a combination
of equilibrium dominance and Cho and Kreps’ (1987) criterion D1 at all information sets off
the equilibrium path, as compared to a natural benchmark equilibrium in which the uninformed
player makes use of all available information (in a sense that will be made precise). The unique
equilibrium, using this notion, is one of immediate separation on monopoly prices. In the limit
price regime, both pooling and separating equilibria may exist and all these involve limit pricing.
I find that in the limit price regime, the basic logic of separating equilibria of a static single-round
setting carries over to the separating equilibria of the dynamic setting. In particular, I find that
by sacrificing enough at some (single) stage of the game, the efficient incumbent may credibly
convey his identity to the entrant. Whether this signalling effectively precludes entry, and is thus
worthwhile from the perspectiveof the incumbent fir m, in turn depends on the entrant’s incentives
to enter. In the dynamic setting, as the future becomes more important, the relevant conditions
needed to deter entry are increasingly unlikely to be satisfied. Specifically, I show that as the
horizon becomes longer, it becomes more difficult to deter entry simply because the entrant’s
one-off cost of entry may not outweigh a long sequence of postentry profits, even if discounted.
Similarly, I show that for a sufficiently patient entrant firm, an infinite sequence of discounted
future profits will outweigh any bounded entry fee and thus, make entry inevitable. In both cases,
adding dynamics to a static limit pricing model makes entry deterrence through limit pricing
more difficult (or impossible) to sustain as an equilibrium outcome. Thus, immediate entry is
likely to result, with each firm setting its respective monopoly price (regardless of the prevailing
regime).
Although these results cast serious doubt on the viability of limit pricing, it should be
mentioned that the basic trade-off found in the static analysis can be recovered in the dynamic
setting, if one disregards the caveats above and assumes all incentive constraints to be sat-
isfied. Even in this case, the dynamics of the model make somewhat unrealistic predictions.
Specifically, one important difference with a static setting is that in the static setting, the ben-
efits from deterring entry are bounded, whereas this is no longer the case in the dynamic set-
ting, if the players are sufficiently patient. For a large enough discount factor and a sufficiently
long horizon, the efficient incumbent needs to press the inefficient incumbent to make strictly
negative profits from mimicking (e.g., by pricing below marginal cost). When the players are
very patient, the short-term losses necessary to credibly signal to be a low-cost incumbent are
unbounded.
Assuming that all the relevant feasibility constraints are satisfied, in the limit price regime,
all equilibria satisfying the D1 type refinement (anchored D1) belong to a single class, consisting
of (i) a (possibly nonzero and possibly infinite) number of periods during which the two types of
incumbent pool; (ii) a period in which the efficient type engages in costly signalling, whereas the
inefficient type reveals himself and invitesentr y; and (iii) continuation playin which the efficient
type charges monopoly prices in all subsequent periods and deters entry, whereas the inefficient
type competes against the entrant.
The welfare properties of these equilibria are not straightforward. It is true, as is the case in the
static benchmark model, that in the period where separation takes place, welfarei sunambiguously
higher than it would be under symmetric information. This is because entry occurs under the
same states of nature as under symmetric information, but the efficient type sets lower prices than
would a monopolist. However, if separation is preceded by periods with pooling, the conclusion
is less clear-cut. This is because pooling deters entry, which counterweights the benefits of lower
C
The RAND Corporation 2017.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT