Does Venture Capital Pay? New Evidence on an Old Question

Published date01 July 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/jcaf.22070
Date01 July 2015
AuthorLuis E. Pereiro
93
© 2015 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Published online in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com).
DOI 10.1002/jcaf.22070
f
e
a
t
u
r
e
a
r
t
i
c
l
e
Does Venture Capital Pay? New
Evidence on an Old Question
Luis E. Pereiro
In the United States,
pension funds invest
close to 10% of their
equity holdings in ven-
ture capital. Among
households, the figure
climbs to a very sub-
stantial 45%. Do such
investments pay?1
To find out, inves-
tors must compare the
returns they realize
on such holdings with
a risk benchmark—a
minimum price, or compensa-
tion, that will be the reward
for the peculiar risks of invest-
ing in venture capital. Such
comparison is, alas, no simple
matter: in contrast to public
equity, venture capital is a
highly illiquid and hazardous
asset class, and we still lack
established models to properly
price its risk. Second, venture
capital is an opaque asset class,
for which data is hard to come
by and usually incomplete,
where assets are not priced con-
tinuously but episodically, and
reporting is subject to a fair
amount of discretion by the
funds’ general partners: ven-
ture capital defies the accurate
measurement of realized
returns.
We address the challenge
head-on by conducting a com-
prehensive review of the evi-
dence on realized U.S. venture
capital returns, which we next
compare with a novel suite of
risk benchmarks especially
suited to this highly special
asset class. Such comparison
unveils a stark, disquieting
asymmetry: whereas venture
capitalists do achieve a siz-
able risk-adjusted return, their
passive investors end up with
negligible excess returns—
simply because they are pay-
ing too large an intermedia-
tion fee.
THE REQUIRED
VENTURE CAPITAL
PREMIUM
Consider three
investors: X, Y, and
Z. X’s equity is
100% allocated to
a fund that tracks
a broad public
stock index, like
the Standard &
Poor’s 500 Index;
by definition, X is
a diversified investor. Assum-
ing a risk-free rate of 4% and a
required market risk premium
of 5%, X’s required return
on public equity would be
4%+5% = 9%.
Y’s equity is, in turn, 100%
invested in a fund that tracks
a broad venture capital (VC)
index, like the Cambridge
Associates (CA) Index. The CA
Index reflects the value of a
large number of minority posi-
tions in VC funds spanning sev-
eral industries. Consequently,
Y can also be considered a
diversified investor—but within
the VC market only. Finally,
Z is a venture capitalist whose
equity is 100% invested in a
Using a novel set of risk benchmarks, the author
analyzes the performance of U.S. venture capital.
Findings show, over the long term, that venture
capitalists have achieved a risk-adjusted return of
5.16%. In stark contrast, their passive capital pro-
viders have pocketed a dismal, close-to-nil return
on venture capital. The author suggests a method
to solve this imbalance—a practical way for pas-
sive investors to negotiate a fairer split of returns
with venture capitalists. © 2015 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT