Does value chain integration dampen producer price developments? Evidence from the European Union

AuthorAgnes Kuegler,Klaus S. Friesenbichler,Andreas Reinstaller
Published date01 January 2021
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12993
Date01 January 2021
World Econ. 2021;44:89–106. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/twec
|
89
© 2020 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Received: 7 August 2019
|
Revised: 26 February 2020
|
Accepted: 4 June 2020
DOI: 10.1111/twec.12993
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Does value chain integration dampen producer price
developments? Evidence from the European Union
Klaus S.Friesenbichler
|
AgnesKuegler
|
AndreasReinstaller
Austrian Institute of Economic Research (WIFO), Vienna, Austria
Funding information
Horizon 2020 Framework Programme; European Commission, DG GROW within the Framework Service, Grant/Award
Number: ENTR and /300/PP/2013/FC
KEYWORDS
EU integration, inflation, producer prices, Single Market, value chains
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Economic integration, in particular through value chain trade, should help cutting prices. Prices of
goods and services should fall because of increased competition and a more efficient allocation of
resources in an integrated economic area (Melitz & Ottaviano,2008). In addition, increased market
integration is thought to lead to a decoupling of domestic demand and production capacity, thereby
limiting the possibility that inflation rises as domestic demand builds up (Dexter, Levi, & Nault,2005;
Goldberg & Verboven,2005).
This paper sets out to test this conjecture. It uses the Single Market of the EU as an example of an
economically integrated area. We study value chains acting as transmission channels through which
Single Market integration affects producer prices at the sector level. We use a novel set of indicators
to capture different aspects of value chain trade integration. The analysis controls for other layers of
integration: Eurozone membership and the effect of EU accession. These capture additional legal and
institutional aspects of market integration. Hence, the paper empirically extends previous research,
which either focused on inputs, such as raw materials, or differences between broadly defined sectors
such as tradables and non-tradables.
The contribution to the literature is threefold: first, the paper establishes an empirical link between
the cumulated effects of trade integration along value chains and producer price dynamics. Trade theory
predicts that greater trade openness is accompanied by falling prices (Melitz & Ottaviano,2008). This
would imply that economic integration goes also along with lower inflation rates. Recent theorising and
empirical analyses of trade have explained firm level price dynamics either through firm productivity on
the supply-side (Luttmer,2007; Melitz,2003) or final consumer preferences on the demand side (Foster
& Potts,2006). While there is some evidence for a few countries that trade openness reduces prices
(Chen,2009), little is known on how such direct effects cumulate along value chains. The accession to a
large common market triggers a restructuring of supply relations and changes preferences, which we use
in this paper to study this underexposed aspect of market integration. The analysis distinguishes between
90
|
FRIESENBICHLER Et aL.
forward and backward integration and also controls for possible endogeneity issues with respect to EU
accession. Hence, the results contribute to the development of a better understanding of the impact of
market integration on macroeconomic price dynamics (Angeloni etal.,2006).
Second, we address the issue of quantifying value chain integration, thus contributing to the toolset of
applied economic research. We explicitly consider both upstream and downstream effects over the value
chain. In upstream relationships, prices are determined by prices of inputs incorporated in production. In
downstream relationships, prices may be affected by complementarities between inputs or non-constant
returns to scale. Our analysis considers both channels. We draw on the World Input-Output Database
(WIOD) to construct measures of both backward and forward linkages at the country-sector level for the
period 2000–14. This allows for a nuanced discussion of the effects of integration on producer prices. In
addition, we control for EU accession, which affects institutions as well as policy decisions and joining
the Eurozone, which implies entering a pegged exchange rate regime. Thus, we propose a comprehen-
sive, novel and easily reproducible set of EU market integration indicators.
Third, this paper is policy relevant. One of the arguably biggest achievements of the EU is the establish-
ment of the Single Market, which it defines as ‘one territory without any internal borders or other regula-
tory obstacles to the free movement of goods and services. A functioning Single Market stimulates
competition and trade, improves efficiency, raises quality, and helps cut prices.’ (Cit. DG Growth).1 Yet, an
empirical test that market integration helps cutting prices is yet lacking, even though this question is highly
relevant for the debate about economic integration and value chain trade (dis-)integration processes.
2
|
PRODUCER PRICES, TRADE AND MARKET
INTEGRATION IN THE EU
Theory predicts a negative effect of trade on prices. As markets become bigger and product variety
and the number of firms increases, competition rises, and firms gain lower mark-ups. Increasing mar-
ket efficiency implies a dampening effect on prices (Melitz & Ottaviano,2008).
A first descriptive analyses of producer price inflation hints at significant heterogeneity between
sector types and countries. Starting with sector-specific price indices Figure1 splits the economy into
broadly defined non-tradable and tradable sectors (Sachs & Larraine,1993; see online Appendix S1).
The main benefits of the Single Market unfold through the trade of commodities. If market integration
indeed has a taming effect on producer price inflation, one would expect that in economies in which
the tradable sector has a larger share in value added producer price inflation should be lower. However,
the data show heterogeneous price developments across countries and sectors (see also Appendix S1).
Price increases tend to be higher in CEE countries than in core European or countries in Southern
Europe. The price developments of tradables and non-tradables are remarkably similar in the bulk of
countries of the sample. However, especially in Finland, Romania, Latvia, Slovakia and the Czech
Republic the producer prices of non-tradables seem to increase faster than in tradables.2
1See https://ec.europa.eu/growt h/single-market_en (accessed on 28 June 2019).
2The price indices have been calculated in a stepwise procedure. First, we define deterministic industry weights, and calculate the
share of tradables and non-tradables for the entire period analysed (2000–14). The total deflated value added produced by each
sector is computed and then weighted by the overall value added. Second, these time- and country-invariant industry weights are
used to compute the aggregate shares of tradables and non-tradables. Due to missing values in some countries’ samples, the
sections T (Activities of households as employers; undifferentiated goods- and services-producing activities of households for
own use) and U (Activities of extraterritorial organisations and bodies) are not considered. Third, the deflators are recalculated so
that they use the year 2000 as the common base. These indices then allow comparing the price dynamics of both tradables and
non-tradables. To illustrate the differences, we use the geometric average over time to show annualised inflation rates.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT