Does Reform Prevent Rebellion? Evidence From Russia’s Emancipation of the Serfs

AuthorTricia D. Olsen,Evgeny Finkel,Scott Gehlbach
Date01 July 2015
DOI10.1177/0010414014565887
Published date01 July 2015
Subject MatterArticles
Comparative Political Studies
2015, Vol. 48(8) 984 –1019
© The Author(s) 2015
Reprints and permissions:
sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0010414014565887
cps.sagepub.com
Article
Does Reform Prevent
Rebellion? Evidence
From Russia’s
Emancipation of the
Serfs
Evgeny Finkel1, Scott Gehlbach2,
and Tricia D. Olsen3
Abstract
Contemporary models of political economy suggest that reforms intended
to reduce grievances should curtail unrest, a perspective at odds with
many traditional accounts of reform and rebellion. We explore the impact
of reform on rebellion with a new data set on peasant disturbances in
19th-century Russia. Using a difference-in-differences design that exploits
the timing of various peasant reforms, we document a large increase in
disturbances among former serfs following the Emancipation Reform of
1861, a development counter to reformers’ intent. Our analysis suggests
that this outcome was driven by peasants’ disappointment with the reform’s
design and implementation—the consequence of elite capture in the context
of a generally weak state—and heightened expectations of what could be
achieved through coordinated action. Reform-related disturbances were
most pronounced in provinces where commune organization facilitated
collective action and where fertile soil provoked contestation over land.
1George Washington University, DC, USA
2University of Wisconsin–Madison, WI, USA
3University of Denver, CO, USA
Corresponding Author:
Scott Gehlbach, Professor of Political Science, University of Wisconsin–Madison, 110 North
Hall, 1050 Bascom Mall, Madison, WI 53706, USA.
Email: gehlbach@polisci.wisc.edu
565887CPSXXX10.1177/0010414014565887Comparative Political StudiesFinkel et al.
research-article2015
Finkel et al. 985
Keywords
revolution, democratization and regime change, East European politics,
Russia/former Soviet Union, conflict processes
Many contemporary models of political economy suggest that policy and
institutional change are driven by fear of social unrest (e.g., Acemoglu &
Robinson, 2006; Ansell & Samuels, 2010; Boix, 2003; Dunning, 2008;
Gandhi & Przeworski, 2006; Svolik, 2012). Although details differ, such
models are typically characterized by a bargaining environment in which an
excluded group has the ability to impose a costly settlement—often through
large-scale social unrest—if bargaining breaks down. Reform (policy or
institutional change intended to improve the welfare of the excluded group)
reduces the likelihood that this option is exercised—the only alternative to
elites being repression, which is itself costly.1 As summarized by Adam
Przeworski, “extensions of rights are a response of the incumbent holders of
rights to revolutionary threats by the excluded” (Przeworski, 2009, p. 292).
Although it is intuitive that reforms intended to reduce grievances should
reduce unrest, earlier important work suggests a more ambiguous relation-
ship between reform and rebellion, especially in traditional societies.
Huntington (1968), for example, suggests that reform can be either a “cata-
lyst” or “substitute” for political instability, as reform may raise expectations
among excluded groups even as it addresses long-standing grievances.
Skocpol (1979) shows how reform driven by international pressures but con-
strained by elite interests can paradoxically create the conditions for rebel-
lion, especially in the context of preexisting capacity for collective action
among the peasantry. Scott (1976), in turn, demonstrates that modernizing
reforms can undermine norms that ensure subsistence lifestyles, thus foster-
ing grievances that drive rebellion, even if such reforms increase expected
income.2
What is the impact of reform on rebellion? We provide new evidence on
this question with a novel data set of peasant disturbances in 19th-century
Russia. Our data allow us to examine the impact of a particular reform
designed to prevent social disorder: Tsar Alexander II’s emancipation of the
serfs in 1861. Long-simmering unrest among peasants bound to the nobility,
punctuated by occasional spasms of intense violence, had encouraged various
acts of peasant reform throughout the Russian Empire but never emancipa-
tion of the serfs in Russia proper. In the wake of the Crimean War, which led
to renewed peasant disturbances as well as a perception that Russia’s institu-
tions were outdated, Alexander finally declared to the Moscow nobility in
1856 that it was better to end serfdom “from above” than to wait for it to
986 Comparative Political Studies 48(8)
happen “from below.” This was more than public rhetoric: The tsar’s per-
sonal reaction to reports by members of his Secret Committee on the Peasant
Question indicate a fear of spontaneous peasant revolution (Zaionchkovskii,
1968, Chapter 2).
Our focus on Russian Emancipation represents a “most-likely” research
design (e.g., Eckstein, 1975; Gerring, 2007), in which the deck is intention-
ally stacked in favor of some theoretical prior—here, that reform reduces
unrest. In addition to the reality that preventing unrest was a primary goal of
the Emancipation Reform of 1861, there were various other factors that made
such an outcome likely. Discontent among Russian serfs (as with peasants
generally, suggests Huntington, 1968) was primarily distributive, not ide-
ational, implying that the peasantry may have been comparatively easy to
buy off.3 In addition, reform did not pose the sort of commitment problem
that would make it difficult to avoid unrest (Acemoglu & Robinson, 2006).
As we discuss below, property rights were for years after emancipation deter-
mined by land charters that were negotiated during the reform process.
Indeed, it is precisely the commitment value of the charters that led to the
contestation that we document. Finally, reform arguably led to no immediate
change in the ease of rebellion.
The utility of the Russian case can be observed by comparing it with other
instances of 19th-century reform: emancipation of the serfs in neighboring
Austria–Hungary and Prussia. As oppressive as serfdom was in those regions,
peasants were materially better off at the time of reform than they were in
Russia, with greater right to land. Peasant revolt was not the ever-present
danger that it was further east: Prussian peasants were by and large an “obedi-
ent lot” (Kieniewicz, 1969, p. 59), and “[t]he peasantry was no danger to the
Austrian state” (Link, 1974, p. 174). Consequently, reform was driven in both
Austria–Hungary and Prussia in substantial part by a desire to improve state
finances, not to prevent unrest (Blum, 1948; Eddie, 2013). Moreover, and
largely in contrast to the Russian case, reform proceeded gradually over
decades of evolution of the state apparatus (Kosáry, 1941), complicating
identification of any causal effect of reform on rebellion.
Thus, various factors skewed the distribution of likely outcomes in the
direction of reducing unrest among the Russian peasantry. Yet, as we demon-
strate with a difference-in-differences design that exploits the differential
impact of reform on serfs and “state peasants” (i.e., peasants who lived on
state lands), respectively, the immediate impact of reform was opposite to
what was intended. Unrest among former serfs accelerated sharply after the
publication of the Emancipation Manifesto in 1861, with disturbances suffi-
ciently dangerous and widespread as to provoke a large military response—
that is, repression. Even after the immediate crisis had passed, those rebellions

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT