Does Predatory Pricing Exist? Economic Theory and the Courts after Brooke Group

AuthorRichard O. Zerbe,Michael T. Mumford
Published date01 December 1996
Date01 December 1996
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/0003603X9604100410
Subject MatterArticle
The Antitrust Bulletin/Winter 1996
Does predatory pricing exist?
Economic theory and the courts
after Brooke Group
BY RICHARD O. ZERBE, JR.* and
MICHAEL T. MUMFORD**
1. The
Areeda-
Turner
rule
949
Professors Areeda and Turner made innumerable contributions to
antitrust and one of those contributions for which they are most
famous is a cost-based test to determine
if
pricing is predatory.
The predatory pricing test proposed by professors Areeda and
Turner in 1975 brought a much-needed element of coherence to
predatory pricing analysis.'
Prior
to that time the controlling
*Professor of Public Affairs and Adjunct Professor of Law, Univer-
sity of Washington.
** Masters Candidate, Graduate School of Public Affairs, Juris Doc-
tor Candidate School of Law, University of Washington.
AUTHORS' NOTE: We would like to thank
Jack
Kirkwood
and
Shane
Woods
for
useful conversation about this article.
Phillip Areeda &Donald Turner, Predatory Pricing and Related
Practices Under Section 2
of
the Sherman Act, 88
HARV.
L.
REV.
637
(1975).
© 1996 by Federal LegalPublications, Inc.
950
The antitrust bulletin
precedent, Utah Pie,2 allowed evidence of predatory intent and an
unreasonably low price to be sufficient evidence of predation. The
rule proposed by Areeda and Turner clarified the definition
of
an
unreasonably low price to be a price below marginal cost that
would be economically irrational and therefore presumptively
unlawful. Because marginal cost is difficult to calculate from
accounting data, average variable cost was proposed as a proxy
for marginal cost.
This approach, or a modification of it, was almost immedi-
ately adopted by most of the circuit courts of appeals, because it
brought
a
logical
and
quantifiable
means
of
distinguishing
between pricing that could have no other economic explanation
than to be predatory, and pricing that merely contributed to robust
competition.>
Circuits
that
have
adopted
the Areeda-
Turner
test include the First, Second, Fifth, and Eighth.' However, as
Denger and Herfort point out, there are still considerable differ-
ences among the circuits about which costs are fixed and which
are variable."
2Utah Pie Co. v. Continental Baking Co., 386 U.S. 685 (1967).
3Michael L.
Freedman,
Predatory Pricing After Brooke Group:
Economic Goals Prevail, 55
ALBANY
L.
REV.
243, 247 (1994).
4Michael L. Denger, 915 PLI/Corp., Predatory Pricing and Prac-
tices, Practising Law Institute: Corporate Law and Practice Course Hand-
book
Series
43 (1996). Also, Michael L.
Denger
&John A.
Herfort,
Predatory Pricing Claims After Brooke Group, 62
ANTITRUST
L.J. 541
(1994).
5Also some commentators have pointed out that at high levels of
output (above capacity) marginal cost and average variable cost tend to
diverge yielding many false negatives: Richard Zerbe &Donald Cooper,
An Empirical
and
Theoretical Comparison
of
Alternative Predation
Rules, 61
TEX.
L. REv. 655, 697 (1982); E.
THOMAS
SULLIVAN
&
HERBERT
HOVENKAMP,
ANTITRUST
LAW,
POLICY
AND
PROCEDURE
699 (3d ed. 1984);
see also Oliver Williamson, Predatory Pricing: A Strategic and Welfare
Analysis, 87
YALE
L.J. 284 (1977). Baumol points out that if considera-
tion
of
predation is confined to those cases in which the prey might be
driven from the market,
that
average variable cost "average avoidable
cost" is the best measure
of
cost for predatory pricing purposes even at
outputs above capacity; William J. Baumol, Predation and the Logic
of
the Average Variable Cost Test, 39 J.L. &
ECON.
49, 49 (April 1996).
Predatory
pricing:
951
Several circuits have held that prices above average total cost
are lawful, but prices between average variable cost (AVC) and
average total costs (ATC) may be unlawful. These include the
Sixth, which places the burden
of
proof on the plaintiff to prove
that prices between AVC and ATC are predatory; the
Eighth-
prices above AVC have a strong presumption
of
illegality; the
Ninth-burden
on plaintiff; the
Tenth-prices
between AVC and
ATC are lawful
absent
other
evidence
of
predation; and the
Eleventh-prices
above AVC create circumstantial evidence of
predatory intent.
The Third, Fourth, Seventh and the District
of
Columbia have
no established rule. Clearly, after
Brooke
Groups it appears that
they must require evidence of below-cost pricing to prove preda-
tion, but the trend seems to be for the court to wait and see what
measure of cost the plaintiff uses in conjunction with other evi-
dence
of
predation.
Contrary to what some have argued, the Areeda- Turner rule
has not been relegated to barely more than a footnote. Rather it
remains an important factor in determining predatory pricing vio-
lations. More appropriately, the legacy
of
the Areeda-Turner rule
continues to inform the debate about predatory pricing, making
standards of evidence more objective and rigorous.
II.
The
use
of
economic
theory
by
the
courts
At one time predation existed as a legal concept but was dis-
counted as an economic possibility.' As legal doctrine has evolved
toward the earlier economic view, the economic view itself has
changed. Now predation may be said to exist economically but,
without stretching current legal doctrine very far, may be said not
to
exist
legally. We argue that the current view
of
predation,
which forms the major precedents since Areeda and Turner pro-
6Brooke Group v. Brown &Williamson Tobacco Corporation, 509
U.S. 209, 242 (1993).
7Daniel Gifford, Predatory Pricing Analysis in the Supreme Court,
39
ANTITRUST
BULL.
431, 432-34 (1994).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT