Does maturity matter? The case of treasury futures volume

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/fut.22039
Date01 October 2019
AuthorAlex Petkevich,Doina Chichernea,Kershen Huang
Published date01 October 2019
J Futures Markets. 2019;39:13011321. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/fut © 2019 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
|
1301
Received: 15 May 2018
|
Accepted: 8 June 2019
DOI: 10.1002/fut.22039
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Does maturity matter? The case of treasury futures volume
Doina Chichernea
1
|
Kershen Huang
2
|
Alex Petkevich
3
1
Reiman School of Finance, Daniels
College of Business, University of Denver,
Denver, Colorado
2
Department of Finance and Economics,
Huizenga College of Business and
Entrepreneurship, Nova Southeastern
University, Fort Lauderdale, Florida
3
Neff Department of Finance, College of
Business and Innovation, University of
Toledo, Toledo, Ohio
Correspondence
Doina Chichernea, Daniels College of
Business, University of Denver, 2101 S
University Blvd, Denver, CO 80210.
Email: doina.chichernea@du.edu
Abstract
We find that Treasury futures volume contains information about future
economic and financial market conditions. Shortand longterm volumes are
economically different: A relatively higher volume in shortterm (longterm)
Treasury futures is countercyclical (procyclical), preceding worse (better)
economic and financial conditions. Further, we construct a single factor from
futures volumes of different maturities that forecasts the performances of
Treasury securities and the corporate debt and equity markets, as well as
macroeconomic conditions. Our results are consistent with the notion that
futures volumes from different market segments reflect differences in beliefs
and contain different information about future financial and economic activity.
KEYWORDS
financial markets, macroeconomic conditions, treasury futures, volume
JEL CLASSIFICATION
G11; G12; G13
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Economists have traditionally relied on the prices of futures contracts to make judgments about the future market and
economic activities. Recent studies suggest, however, that futures volume and open interest contain information that is
not captured in futures prices and can be useful predictors. For example, Hong and Yogo (2012) build a theoretical
model showing that, in the presence of hedging demand and limited risk absorption capacity in the futures markets,
movements in open interest and volume are more informative signals than futures prices; they find that movements in
open interest and volume are procyclical and predict both future economic activity and asset prices.
1
A widely accepted interpretation of volume is that it reflects investorsdisagreement in beliefs, such that heterogeneous
expectations about future economic conditions cause investors to trade with each other. Xiong and Yan (2010), for instance,
show that a reasonable amount of dispersion in priors can generate endogenous wealth fluctuations through the speculative
positions among economic agents. More recently, this line of literature has been growingly rich in emphasizing the term
structure of disagreements. To date, the role of disagreement at different maturities has been discussed in the context of federal
funds rates and GDP output (Andrade, Crump, Eusepi, & Moench, 2016), inflation (Andrade et al., 2016; Capistrán &
Timmermann, 2009), bond yields (Crump, Eusepi, & Moench, 2018), and exchange rates (Cao, Huang, Liu, & MacDonald,
2018). Evident from these studies, disagreements in the shortand longterm segments of a market are economically different.
In this paper, we build on the literature above and study the information in the trading volume of the US Treasury futures
market, conditioning on maturity. We posit that trading volumes contain information about upcoming financial markets and
1
The mechanism driving this predictability in the aforementioned model is essentially underreaction to news and asset prices. The underreaction typically arises due to the graduate diffusion of
information in the market (Hong & Stein, 1999, 2007). The authors argue that futures open interest and volume likely capture underreaction because it is highly related to both contemporaneous and
future news and returns.
macroeconomic activities, based on the argument that volume reflects investorsdisagreement. We ask the following research
question: What do shortand longterm futures volumes tell us about the future financial market and economic conditions?
We are motivated by the idea that economic uncertainty and dispersion in beliefs come hand in hand. Under the
fundamental framework of Patton and Timmermann (2010), market participants make forecasts and take actions based
on a weighted average of information updates and prior beliefs. Since private information is of lower value for the
forecasting of longer term variables, holding all else constant, disagreement is stronger for long horizons. During bad
times, gathering information becomes relatively difficult due to greater uncertainty, which leads to a heavier reliance on
prior beliefs (Van Nieuwerburgh & Veldkamp, 2006; Veldkamp, 2005). To the extent that prior beliefs are sufficiently
dispersed, one would expect higher volumes at the short end of the market as the state of the economy deteriorates.
2
This is consistent with the flight from maturityphenomenon documented in Gorton, Metrick, and Xie (2014): In
expectation of bad times, trading flies from longer maturities to shorter ones, reflecting the overall increase in
uncertainty.
Oppositely, in expectation of the better market and macroeconomic environments, investors face lower uncertainty
and anticipate higher levels of economic activity and productivity (e.g., see Hong & Yogo, 2012). As a result, they have
the incentive to shift to longer term assets.
3
Aside from testing the implications of the flight to maturityargument, examining the maturity dimension of
Treasury futures volume also allows us to better understand the informational role of trading contracts at different
maturities. As investors transmit information regarding the level of heterogeneity in their beliefs through market
activities, the resulting volumes that are observable in different market segments (shortterm vs. longterm)
consequently provide us with different predictions for future market and macroeconomic conditions.
Based on the above rationale, we hypothesize that an increase in relatively shortterm Treasury futures volume
precedes decreasing asset prices and deteriorating general economic conditions. Conversely, an increase in longterm
futures volume is followed by higher levels of economic activity and in turn better financial and macroeconomic
conditions. Considering volume as a reflection of disagreement, our hypothesis is consistent with models such as that
presented in Cujean and Hasler (2017), which shows that during bad times there are spikes in disagreement across
shorter maturities, accompanied by increases in volume.
To test our hypothesis, we collect a unique sample of US Treasury futures volume for different maturities from
Bloomberg. We primarily rely on timeseries techniques (e.g., vector autoregressive [VAR] models) to test whether
trading activity in shortand longterm interest rate futures can predict asset prices and macroeconomic conditions. We
summarize the three key findings in this paper as follows:
1. The shortterm (longterm) Treasury futures volume is negatively (positively) associated with future financial
market performance. We find very consistent predictive power of futures volume for the equity markets. For
corporate bond markets, the effect is evident mostly in junk bonds, where uncertainty is most relevant. On the flip
side, the shortterm (longterm) Treasury futures volume is positively (negatively) associated with lead Treasury
securities performance.
2. The shortterm (longterm) Treasury futures volume is counter (pro)cyclical. We find that an increase in relatively
shortterm futures volumes signals deteriorating future economic conditions, while an increase in relatively long
term volumes is associated with improving future economic trends (our macroeconomic variables include the
growths in GDP, consumption, industrial production, and unemployment).
3. We construct a single, common factor using futures trading volumes that has predictive power across the Treasury
and capital markets, as well as for macroeconomic conditions. This factor, defined as the difference between the
longand shortterm futures trading volumes, strongly predicts lower Treasury returns, better performance by low
rated bonds, and higher equity returns; it is also significantly procyclical in predicting the growths of GDP,
consumption, industrial production, and unemployment.
In sum, we identify the economic difference between trading volumes of shortand longterm Treasury futures as a
source of information about the future financial market and macroeconomic conditions. Controlling for other
2
In the extreme case, the notrade theorem states that if agents do not have differences in prior beliefs, transactions will not occur based on purely informational updates, even when information is
asymmetric (Milgrom & Stokey, 1982; Morris, 1994).
3
In the face of the recent subprime mortgage crisis, there is vast evidence about investors changing the maturity of their trading positions based on their expectations about markets and
macroeconomic activity. For example, Gorton et al. (2014) show that maturity of the debt instruments shortens dramatically during the crisis due to this flight from maturityeffect. Similarly,
Krishnamurthy (2010) also argues that liquidity preferences caused shortening of the maturity in the debt markets.
1302
|
CHICHERNEA ET AL.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT