Does gang membership pay? Illegal and legal earnings through emerging adulthood*

AuthorJean Marie McGloin,David C. Pyrooz,Megan Bears Augustyn
Date01 August 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1745-9125.12208
Published date01 August 2019
Received: 10 April 2018 Revised: 10 January 2019 Accepted: 21 January 2019
DOI: 10.1111/1745-9125.12208
ARTICLE
Does gang membership pay? Illegal and legal
earnings through emerging adulthood*
Megan Bears Augustyn1Jean Marie McGloin2David C. Pyrooz3
1Department of Criminal Justice, The
University of Texasat San Antonio
2Department of Criminology and Criminal
Justice, University of Maryland—College Park
3Department of Sociology, University of
Colorado, Boulder
Correspondence
MeganBears Augustyn, Department of Cr im-
inalJustice, The University of Texas at San
Antonio,4.220 Durango Building, 501 W.
Cesar ChavezBlvd., San Antonio, TX 78207.
Email:megan.augustyn@utsa.edu
*Additionalsupporting information
canbe found in the listing for this arti-
clein t he WileyOnline Library at
http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/
crim.2019.57.issue-3/issuetoc.
Theaut horswould like to thank Christopher
Sullivanand Thomas Loughran for their
assistance.They are also grateful to Dr. David
McDowalland four anonymous reviewersfor
the helpful suggestions.This research relies on
data collected fromt he Pathwaysto Desistance
Study.Support and funding for the data collec-
tionwere provided by the Arizona Governor’s
JusticeCommission, the Centers for Disease
Control,the MacAr thur Foundation, NIDA
(R01DA 019697 05), NIJ (2008-IJ-CX-0023),
OJJDP(2005-JK-FX-K001), t he Pennsylva-
niaCommission on Cr ime & Delinquency,the
RobertWood Johnson Foundation, the William
PennFoundation, and the William T. Grant
Foundation.
Abstract
Gang membership is believed to impede success in the
legitimate economic market while simultaneously support-
ing success in the illegal market. Weextend the study of the
economic effects of gang membership by using a within-
and between-individual analytic design, decomposing gang
membership into multiple statuses (i.e., entering a gang,
continuously in a gang, leaving a gang, and inactive gang
membership), examining legal and illegal earnings simul-
taneously, and accounting for factors endogenous to gang
membership that may contribute to economic achievement.
By using panel data from 1,213 individuals who partici-
pated in the Pathways to Desistance Study to conduct a
multilevel path analysis, we find that active gang mem-
bership status is unrelated to legal earnings. Alternatively,
entering a gang is associated with increased illegal earn-
ings, attributable to changes in delinquent peers and drug
use, whereas leaving a gang has a direct relationship with
decreased illegal earnings. Our results indicate that the pos-
itive economic effectof gang membership (i.e., illegal earn-
ings and total earnings) is short-lived and that, on balance,
the sum of the gang membership experience does not “pay”
in terms of overall earnings.
KEYWORDS
criminal capital, earnings, gangs, multilevel structural equation model
Street gangs are viewed as one avenue to blunt the relegation of the urban underclass to the secondary
labor market (Hagedorn & Macon, 1988; Moore, 1991; Venkatesh & Levitt, 2000; Vigil, 1988).
452 © 2019 American Society of Criminology wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/crim Criminology.2019;57:452–480.
AUGUSTYN ET AL.453
Scholars have portrayed gangs as the quintessential American enterprise of the informal economy,
particularly illicit goods (e.g., Padilla, 1992), positioned to compensate for economic and social
inequalities plaguing entire generations of inner-city youth. The findings from an emerging body of
quantitative research indicate preliminary support for this contention, with gang membership reported
to be associated with at least some illicit success, while seemingly impeding achievement in the
legitimate economy (e.g., Gilman, Hill, & Hawkins, 2014; Krohn, Ward, Thornberry, Lizotte, &
Chu, 2011).
This work is informative, but it would benefit from further consideration. First, despite the
fact that researchers have documented that gang members (and offenders more broadly) generate
earnings through both legal and illegal means (Decker & VanWinkle, 1996; Fagan & Freeman, 1999;
Levitt & Venkatesh, 2000), they have rarely studied both outcomes simultaneously (cf. Carvalho &
Soares, 2016; Uggen & Thompson, 2003). Ideally, one should model both legal and illegal earnings
to determine whether being in a gang, on balance, pays or limits financial dividends. Second,
researchers almost always have adopted a between-persons approach using a binary, static measure
of gang membership—that is, it compares “ever” gang members with “never” gang members. This
approach is problematic because conducting such analyses may pool together periods of active
and nonactive gang status among members or tap into an underlying difference between those
individuals who join gangs and those who do not. The fact that gang membership is dynamic (e.g.,
Pyrooz, Sweeten, & Piquero, 2013) in ways that may be related to earnings is ignored with this
method. Capturing gang entrance, continuity, and exit could provide important insight into the
contours of gang membership’s relationship with earnings. It, therefore, would be beneficial to
use a within-persons analysis to account for the fluid contours of gang membership to capture the
more nuanced relationship between gang status and earnings. Finally, scholars tend not to address
problems of simultaneity in their studies as they do not account for factors endogenous to gang
membership. To be clear, being in a gang may affect earnings through various factors—for example,
criminal and prosocial capital and routine activities—that are known to be associated with financial
success. Specifying such factors may provideinsight into t he mechanismslinking gang membership to
earnings.
In this study, we address these voids by examining legal and illegal earnings associated with gang
membership status using data from the Pathways to Desistance study. This sample of serious offend-
ers in Philadelphia, PA, and Maricopa County, AZ, was interviewed about involvement in gangs and
economic activity 11 times over a 7-year period from late adolescence through emerging adulthood
(Mulvey & Schubert, 2012). The panel nature of the data also offers the opportunity to leverage a
within-individual analysis estimated through a multilevel structural equation modeling framework. In
doing so, we differentiate between periods when a subject entered a gang, wascontinuously active in a
gang, and left a gang, offering a more nuanced sense of “active gang status” in comparison with earn-
ings in periods of nonactive membership. Finally, the data are rich and contain information on several
factors that are endogenous to gang membership, which allows for an improved understanding of the
relationship between gang membership and economic achievement.
1GANG MEMBERSHIP AND ECONOMIC ACHIEVEMENT
When introducing the concept of “criminal embeddedness,” Hagan (1993, pp. 469–473) drew heavily
on gang ethnographies (e.g., Moore, 1991; Padilla, 1992; Sullivan, 1989) to illustrate its dimensions
and linkages to the legitimate and illicit labor markets. Gang membership arguably personifies Hagan’s
(1993) assertion that belonging to criminal networks constrains success in the legitimate labor market

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT