Dodging Dodd‐Frank: Excessive Speculation, Commodities Markets, and the Burden of Proof

Date01 January 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/lapo.12033
AuthorJames W. Williams
Published date01 January 2015
Dodging Dodd-Frank: Excessive Speculation,
Commodities Markets, and the Burden of Proof
JAMES W. WILLIAMS
Inspired by the wave of regulatory rulemaking, which followed the 2008 financial
crisis and the passage of the Dodd-Frank Act, this article examines the efforts of
the Commodities Futures Trading Commission to implement one such rule: Rule
76 FR 4752. Born of concerns with the impact of financial speculators on com-
modities prices, the rule calls for the expanded use of position limits to control
“excessive speculation” in US commodities markets. In documenting the political
and legal life of this rule from its roots in policy reports through to its suspension
by a federal judge, the article explores the place of “evidence” in the rulemaking
process. Particular attention is devoted to the growing evidentiary burden placed
on financial regulators who are expected to frame market problems in terms of
quantitative, price-based forms of harm. In the case of position limits, this has
involved statistical analyses of the causal connections between excessive specula-
tion and commodities prices and the use of a single statistical test: Granger
causality. By examining the parameters and limitations of this test, the article
offers a valuable window into the unique challenges of financial regulation and
their roots in questions of knowledge, evidence, and proof.
INTRODUCTION
Passed in the wake of the financial crisis of 2008, the Dodd-Frank Wall Street
Reform and Consumer Protection Act (2010) has been hailed as one of the
most extensive interventions in US financial markets since the New Deal era
reforms of the 1930s. Mandating 348 rulemakings across twenty different
agencies, the legislative package has spurred a torrent of regulatory
rulemaking on matters ranging from proprietary trading, to capital require-
ments, to greater market transparency. Despite this burst of legislative energy,
the implementation of these rules has been halting to say the least. Many
proposed rules have foundered in the face of fierce opposition and intense
industry lobbying both behind the scenes and through the formal comment
I would like to thank the editor and the three anonymous reviewers for their helpful comments
and valuable insights. They were instrumental in revising the article.
Address correspondence to James W. Williams, Department of Social Science, York Univer-
sity, 4700 Keele Street, Toronto, Ontario, Canada M3J 1P3. Telephone: 416-736-2100 x 20547;
E-mail: jamesw1@yorku.ca.
bs_bs_banner
LAW & POLICY, Vol. 37, Nos 1–2, January–April 2015 ISSN 0265–8240
© 2015 The Author
Law & Policy © 2015 The University of Denver/Colorado Seminary
doi: 10.1111/lapo.12033
process. None of this is especially surprising. Resistance, delay, and circum-
vention are age-old industry tactics. And yet, the barriers thrown in the way of
Dodd-Frank are not simply a case of business as usual. In a series of
groundbreaking cases, key rules promulgated by the Securities Exchange
Commission (SEC) and the Commodity Futures Trading Commission
(CFTC) have been challenged and subsequently vacated primarily on eviden-
tiary grounds with district courts chiding the agencies for their failure to
provide sufficiently robust cost-benefit analyses. Through these forms of
judicial intervention, matters of evidence, the treatment of empirical research,
and the ability to articulate, quantify, and monetize projected costs and
benefits have emerged as central to the Dodd-Frank implementation effort.
This article takes aim at these shifting standards of regulatory rulemaking
in the financial sphere and their roots in evidentiary formats and econometric
techniques, which privilege quantitative and statistical forms of analysis. The
specific context for this examination is one of the less widely acknowledged
although no less controversial rules emanating from Dodd-Frank, Rule 76
FR 4752.1Motivated less by the subprime crisis and more by the crisis of
escalating food and energy prices, this provision mandates the CFTC to use
position limits2to restrict the flow of speculative capital into markets ranging
from metals, to oil and gas, to agricultural commodities. The ensuing
rulemaking process has been extremely contentious with the rule triggering
thousands of comment letters as well as a lawsuit against the CFTC spear-
headed by two Wall Street trade groups. At the center of these debates have
been the evidentiary grounds of the rule itself. Drawing from correlational
and experiential evidence, proponents have argued that “excessive specula-
tion” is clearly implicated in harmful price swings and that position limits are
a necessary remedy. Detractors have meanwhile pointed to academic
research, which they claim is more scientifically robust and which has failed
to detect a clear causal relationship between speculative positions and com-
modity price movements thus raising doubts about the merits of an expanded
position limits regime. In documenting these competing views of “acceptable
evidence,” and examining how the latter came to dominate as the issue
migrated from the policy to the judicial sphere, this article offers a valuable
window into the increasingly difficult work of financial regulation and the
challenge of articulating market troubles in terms of specific price-based
effects and quantitative signs of harm. An essential question is thus the type
of evidentiary burden being imposed on regulators as a result of Dodd-Frank
maneuverings and the ability of regulators, using available tools, data, and
resources, to satisfy this burden.
The analysis proceeds through the following sections. The first section
situates the position limits debate in the context of larger developments
involving the role of evidence and expertise in the legal and regulatory sphere.
This includes the growing reliance on scientific and statistical measures of
harm as well as the greater willingness of the courts to step in as the arbiters
of last resort determining whether regulators have satisfied their obligations
120 LAW & POLICY January–April 2015
© 2015 The Author
Law & Policy © 2015 The University of Denver/Colorado Seminary
in individual cases. The next section delves into the position limits debate
exploring the different forms of evidence brought to bear on the relationship
between “excessive speculation” and commodities prices and examining how
the standards of acceptable evidence shifted as the debate migrated through
various social, political, and legal spheres. The third section takes aim at the
academic research used to undergird claims that excessive speculation is not
a significant driver of commodities prices, research that relies almost exclu-
sively on a single econometric test. In examining the limitations of this test,
known as Granger causality, and its ability to distill the causal connections
between investor positions and price movements, the push toward quantifi-
cation is placed in a more critical light with available econometric methods
constrained both by internal parameters and sensitivities and by a limited
view of “price” itself. Drawing from recent work in the Social Studies of
Finance (SSF), an alternative view of price as a social, material, and techno-
logical accomplishment is presented, which further problematizes not only
the search for conclusive evidence or “proof” of the causal connections
between speculative investments and observed price movements, but also the
ability of econometrics to provide clear and irrefutable articulations of price-
based forms of financial harm. The conclusion draws out the implications of
this analysis for regulatory rulemaking, including the benefits of conceiving
of regulatory struggles in terms of epistemic challenges and competing con-
structions of proof as opposed to well-worn accounts of capture, complicity,
and purely interest-based politics.
LAW, SCIENCE, AND FINANCIAL REGULATION
The debate over position limits and the links between speculation and com-
modities prices is set against the backdrop of a series of larger transforma-
tions in the relationships between law and science, and the shifting standards
and evidentiary thresholds governing what qualifies or counts as acceptable
evidence in legal and regulatory proceedings (Edmond 2004; Mercer 2002;
Jasanoff 1995). Emerging from campaigns against “junk science” in the
1980s and early 1990s, a key moment in these transformations was a shift in
the admissibility standards for expert evidence in US civil law, specifically the
Daubert trilogy of cases (Daubert v Merrell Dow Pharmaceuticals 1993;
General Electric Co. v Joiner 1997; Kumho Tire Co. v Carmichael 1999),
which not only placed more power in the hands of judges to determine
whether to admit expert testimony, but also codified a series of specific
standards according to which this evidence is to be adjudged. This included
an emphasis on methodological “gold standards,” such as the randomized
controlled trial and the epidemiological study as well as evidence that can be
scientifically verified and validated based on epistemic conventions of “sound
science,” namely, falsifiability, peer review, and known error rates. Whether
embedded in Daubert itself, or how judges have subsequently taken up the
Williams DODGING DODD-FRANK 121
© 2015 The Author
Law & Policy © 2015 The University of Denver/Colorado Seminary

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT