Do US Macroeconomic Forecasters Exaggerate their Differences?

AuthorMichael P. Clements
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/for.2358
Published date01 December 2015
Date01 December 2015
Journal of Forecasting,J. Forecast. 34, 649–660 (2015)
Published online 18 August 2015 in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com)DOI: 10.1002/for.2358
Do US Macroeconomic Forecasters Exaggerate
their Differences?
MICHAEL P. CLEMENTS
ICMA Centre, Henley Business School, University of Reading, UK
ABSTRACT
Application of the Bernhardt et al. (Journal of Financial Economics 2006; 80(3): 657–675) test of herding to the
calendar-year annual output growth and inflation forecasts suggests forecasters tend to exaggerate their differences,
except at the shortest horizon, when they tend to herd. We consider whether these types of behaviour can help to
explain the puzzle that professional forecasters sometimes make point predictions and histogram forecasts which are
mutually inconsistent. Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
KEY WORDS macro-forecasting; imitative behaviour; histogram forecasts; point predictions
INTRODUCTION
It is generally understood that economic forecasters may have incentives to act strategically in the sense of seeking
to enhance their reputations (see, among others, Lamont, 2002; Ehrbeck and Waldmann, 1996; Laster et al., 1999;
Ottaviani and Sorensen, 2006). For example, Lamont (2002, p. 265) notes that besides minimizing squared forecast
errors agents may set their forecasts to ‘optimize profits or wages, credibility, shock value, marketability, political
power...’.Muchoftheempirical literature on testing the influence of factors other than accuracy on the determi-
nation of agents’ forecasts rests on the notion of herding—whether forecasters take into account the views of others
when they produce their forecasts. This may be manifest in forecasters skewing their optimal forecast towards the
consensus view, or artificially exaggerating the difference between their forecast and the consensus, where optimal
is to be understood in the narrow sense of maximizing the expected accuracy of the forecast (e.g. minimizing the
expected squared forecast error). Indeed, Lamont (2002) supposes that forecasters’ actual loss functions may contain
terms in the difference between the forecast and the consensus, as well as conventional accuracy measures such as
the absolute forecast error.
The focus of this paper is whether the respondents to the US Survey of Professional Forecasters (US-SPF) take into
account the consensus view when they issue their forecasts of US output growth and inflation. Compared to studies
such as Lamont (2002), where the individual forecasters are identified and their track performance is public knowl-
edge, the SPF respondents are anonymous (although each respondent has a unique identifier, so that individuals can
be tracked over time). One might suspect this would weaken the extent to which the forecasters behave strategically,
but alternatively, if the respondents report the same forecasts to the SPF as they make public through other spheres,
these issues remain pertinent. We regard it as a matter that can only be determined by an empirical study. We wish to
discover whether herding behaviour depends on the forecast horizon. Forecasters may behave differently when pro-
viding their expectations of relatively distant events compared to short-horizon forecasts. In our study the forecast
horizons span one-quarter to 1-year-ahead forecasts. As well as exploring forecast behaviour across different hori-
zons, we also explore behaviour by type of forecaster and assess whether forecasters working in firms characterized
as financial service providers systematically differ from those in non-financial service firms.
The behaviour of the forecasters that take part in the US-SPF is of interest in itself as part of the endeavour to
better understand the actual expectations formation process of economic agents, given the pre-eminence of the US-
SPF.1But, in addition, of particular interest is whether strategicbehaviour is responsible in part for the inconsistencies
between the respondents’ reported probability distributions and point predictions, as documented by Engelberg et al.
(2009) and Clements (2009, 2010).
Testing for herding is not straightforward, as individuals’ forecasts will tend to cluster together to the extent that
they share the same information, irrespective of whether they consider the consensus view when they form their
forecasts. There have been a number of influential papers on herding. Batchelor and Dua (1992) find that forecasters
Correspondence to: Michael P. Clements, ICMA Centre, Henley Business School, University of Reading, Reading RG6 6BA, UK. E-mail:
m.p.clements@reading.ac.uk
1The US SPF has been an important source of data for research on expectations formation. As of 21 April 2014, the Academic Bibliography main-
tained by the Philadelphia Fed listed 79 research papers based on the SPF forecast data: see http://www.philadelphiafed.org/research-and-data/
real-time-center/survey-of- professional-forecasters/academic-bibliography.cfm.
Copyright © 2015 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT