Do types of foreign capital matter for income equality?

Date01 December 2020
AuthorInmee Baek,Andrew Chia
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12984
Published date01 December 2020
World Econ. 2020;43:3243–3261. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/twec
|
3243
© 2020 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Received: 10 June 2019
|
Revised: 2 February 2020
|
Accepted: 13 April 2020
DOI: 10.1111/twec.12984
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Do types of foreign capital matter for income
equality?
InmeeBaek1
|
AndrewChia2
1Department of Economics, Suffolk University, Boston, MA, USA
2School of Engineering and Applied Sciences, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA, USA
KEYWORDS
financial integration, foreign direct investment, globalisation, income inequality
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Deeper financial integration and increased trade between economies over the last decades have co-
incided with an exacerbation of income inequality, and a concentration of wealth. The distributional
impact of economic globalisation is thus at the centre of debates around the world. Even though there
has been extensive research in identifying linkages between income inequality and trade, the role of
financial integration in influencing inequality is far less well-studied. In particular, studies on different
channels in financial integration are very limited. In this study, we attempt to answer the following
questions: in financial globalisation, do different types of foreign capital have different distributional
impact? If so, what type of capital exacerbates or reduces income inequality?
Analysis of economic globalisation is centred on trade openness and financial integration. This
paper examines how the degree of financial integration and composition of different types of foreign
capital shapes inequality. Previous studies on this issue have mostly used a composite measure of
financial openness and often suggest mixed findings on the link between financial globalisation and
income inequality. If different channels of financial integration have contrasting impact on income
inequality, then the failure to differentiate them will result in incomplete inferences on the re-distribu-
tional implications of cross-border capital integration.
The present study expands on the existing literature in the following ways. First, our empirical ex-
ercise focuses on the composition of cross-border capital, such as direct investment, portfolio invest-
ment and debt. Other studies have tended to include all the different types of foreign capital, expressed
as a fraction of GDP, together in the same specification.1 We depart from this by examining each type
of foreign capital individually and express them as a fraction of overall financial integration, which we
also separately control for. This allows us to differentiate the impact of changes in composition of
cross-border capital flows from a general increase in the degree of financial integration. Second, our
analysis classifies different types of foreign capital by their instrument—debt and equity—and by
1For example, see Jaumotte et al. (2013), Asteriou et al. (2014), and Gozgor and Ranjan (2017).
3244
|
BAEK And CHIA
function. Furthermore, we depart from the majority of existing literature by employing dynamic panel
data methods as opposed to a static panel, to capture the dynamic impact of financial globalisation on
income inequality.
The main finding of our empirical study is that different types of foreign capital have contrasting
distributional effects, and thus, the make-up of foreign capital matters in income inequality. For exam-
ple, financial integration through a greater share of debt-creating capital increases income inequality.
A higher dependency on direct investment in total financial integration has a significantly beneficial
impact on income distribution; the converse is true for loans and credit, while the share of portfolio
investment has no significant effect. This contrasting result could account for the ambiguous distribu-
tional effect of aggregated financial globalisation. Additionally, we find that trade openness increases
income inequality in advanced economies but reduces it in emerging economies. Moreover, domestic
factors such as education, technology intensity in production, economic structure, depth of financial
market and fiscal policy have a significant effect on income inequality.
The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 covers the literature review, followed by
the model and data in Section 3. Section 4 presents our empirical results. Section 5 concludes.
2
|
LITERATURE REVIEW
Globalisation is multi-faceted, reflecting economic, social, cultural and political aspects.2 We focus
on the consequences of globalisation on income distribution primarily influenced by increased eco-
nomic integration. There has been extensive study of the distributional impact of economic integration
through increased trade openness, both empirically and theoretically. However, there is still contro-
versy surrounding the impact of trade openness on inequality across both advanced and developing
economies, with empirical findings conflicting with theoretical predictions.
Traditional theory assesses the impact of trade on income inequality through the framework of
comparative advantage analysis in the Heckscher–Ohlin model and the Stolper–Samuelson theorem.
Together, they predict that trade globalisation will see countries which have a comparative advantage
in low-skilled labour, such as emerging economies, experience growth in their low-skilled, labour in-
tensive industries. This will benefit workers in such industries, and thus, developing countries should
see a reduction in income inequality from increased trade. Conversely, countries with a comparative
advantage in high-skilled labour and capital such as advanced economies will experience a rising in-
come inequality in response to increasing trade globalisation. However, some empirical studies from
the 1990s conflict with the prediction that trade integration would lead to lower income inequality in
developing countries. During the period, trade integration and income inequality grew in tandem in
many developing countries. In response, a number of new theories have been developed to explain
why increased trade is associated with increased income inequality in developing countries. These
include theories on the skill premium, heterogeneous-firms monopolistic competition, skill-based
technology change and labour market frictions.3
2In developing ‘The KOF index of globalisation’, Dreher (2006) defines globalisation as the process of creating networks of
connections among actors at multi-continental distances, mediated through a variety of flows including people, information
and ideas, capital and goods. An extensive survey of the studies using the KOF index is included in Potrafke (2015). The
KOF index was revised by Gozgor (2018). Using the revised KOF index, the role of globalisation is examined in explaining a
wide range of economic issues such as economic growth (Gozgor, 2018), taxation (Jha & Gozgor, 2019) and social
expenditures (Potrafke, 2019).
3For a survey of the link between trade and income inequality, see Harrison et al. (2010).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT