Do IMF fiscal forecasts add value?

Published date01 September 2018
Date01 September 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/for.2527
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Do IMF fiscal forecasts add value?
Zidong An
1,3
| João Tovar Jalles
2
| Prakash Loungani
3
| Ricardo M. Sousa
4,5
1
College of Arts and Sciences, American
University, Washington, DC, USA
2
Fiscal Affairs Department, International
Monetary Fund, Washington, DC, USA
3
Research Department, International
Monetary Fund, Washington, DC, USA
4
Department of Economics and Economic
Policies Research Unit (NIPE), University
of Minho, Braga, Portugal
5
LSE Alumni Association, London School
of Economics and Political Science,
London, UK
Correspondence
João Tovar Jalles, Research Department,
International Monetary Fund, 700 19th
Street NW, Washington, DC, 20431, USA.
Email: jjalles@imf.org
Abstract
We used a panel of 29 advanced and emerging market countries to investigate
whether the IMF's World Economic Outlook (WEO) fiscal forecasts add value
in terms of forecast accuracy and information content, relative to private sector
forecasts (from Consensus Economics). We find that: (i) WEO forecasts are not
significantly less accurate than Consensus forecasts; (ii) WEO and Consensus
forecasts tend to mutually encompass one another; and (iii) each source of
forecasts appears to contain some information that is not embedded in the
other source.
KEYWORDS
asymmetry, bias, budget balance, efficiency, forecast comparison, information rigidity
1|INTRODUCTION
Understanding budgetary dynamics is a very important
as well as a timely and timeless question. Forecasting it
correctly, however, seems an equally important issue,
particularly in a context where social expenditure is ris-
ing and fiscal policy action is limited in many countries
given the continued public finance retrenchment. While
the literature on forecast performance broadly supports
the view that fiscal forecasts tend to be biased and inac-
curate (Jonung & Larch, 2006), assessing the perfor-
mance of fiscal forecasts emanating from different
sources for a heterogeneous panel of advanced and
emerging market countries has not been sufficiently cov-
ered in the literature. In fact, it is well known that gov-
ernments are often subject to pressures that lead to the
production of budget balance forecasts that are too opti-
mistic (Frankel, 2012). A fair witness of the skepticism
that typically surrounds fiscal forecasts by local authori-
ties is assembled in several studies in the literature that
confirm the lack of accuracy of such forecasts (Leal,
Perez, Tujula, & Vidal, 2008). For instance, Frankel
(2011) shows that the actual fiscal balance outcomes
are systematically lower than the official forecasts
produced by governments; that is, there is evidence of a
significantly positive bias in fiscal forecasts.
This empirical observation raises a number of rele-
vant questions. Do fiscal forecasts produced by interna-
tional organizations outperform those of private sector
agencies? Can national government forecasts be
complemented by different sources of forecasts? Is there
any information content in forecasts from strengthened
national institutions or supranational organizations that
is not embedded in private sector forecasts?
In this paper, we analyze these issues through the lens
of a rigorous econometric assessment. More specifically,
we start by highlighting that while standard measures,
such as the mean forecast error (ME), the mean absolute
error (MAE), or the root mean squared error (RMSE), are
valuable when evaluating the forecast performance of a
given institution (Artis & Marcellino, 2001; Keereman,
1999), they are much less informative about the relative
performance of competingsources of forecasts. For this
reason, we directly test the significance of differences in
mean square errors between: (i) the IMF's World Eco-
nomic Outlook (WEO) fiscal forecasts (i.e., an
Received: 7 April 2017 Revised: 12 December 2017 Accepted: 2 April 2018
DOI: 10.1002/for.2527
650 Copyright © 2018 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Journal of Forecasting. 2018;37:650665.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/for
international organization); and (ii) the fiscal forecasts of
Consensus Economics (i.e., a privatesector agency).
We accomplish such a goal by relying on two major
tests. The first one is test developed by Ashley, Granger,
and Schmalensee (1980), which regresses the differences
in errors from two forecasts on the sums of these errors.
This allows us to compare the accuracy of WEO forecasts
visàvis Consensus Economics forecasts. The second test
follows the procedure put forward by Fair and Shiller
(1990), and aims at assessing whether one forecast domi-
nates the other one in terms of information content.
Therefore, by combining the information content of two
sets of forecasts into a single combinedforecast, the test
makes it possible to investigate whether each forecast
contains information that is not already embedded in
the other forecast.
Using data for a panel of 29 advanced and emerging
market countries over the period 19932014, we find that
WEO forecasts are not significantly less accurate than
Consensus forecasts. Additionally, WEO and Consensus
forecasts tend to mutually encompass one another. This
suggests that a combined forecast might yield better
results. Moreover, each source of forecasts appears to
contain some information that is not already included
in the other source.
Our results also confirm the bias toward optimism
that typically characterizes fiscal forecasts. We show
that Consensus forecasts tend to be more optimistic that
WEO forecasts, especially for the subsample of emerging
market economies where WEO forecasts are actually pes-
simistic. Despite this, traditional metrics of forecast accu-
racy suggest that WEO forecasts outperform Consensus
forecasts both across the time horizon dimension and
country groups.
In addition, we find that WEO forecasts are more effi-
cient than Consensus forecasts, with the latter generally
being inefficient. In the case of emerging markets, the
lack of forecast efficiency accrues to the fact that past
errors are repeated in the present. For advanced econo-
mies, inefficiency also reflects that the model from which
forecasts are generated is not a minimumvariance
model. The empirical results also convey the message that
inefficiency is still observed once we take asymmetry into
account. Indeed, both positive and negative past forecast
errors are correlated with present forecast errors.
Finally, we show that information rigidity is a feature
of Consensus forecasts, but less so for WEO forecasts:
new information tends to be incorporated more quickly
in the revised forecasts of the latter than the former.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2
describes the data. Section 3 presents the econometric
methodology. Section 4 discusses the empirical results.
Finally, Section 5 concludes.
2|DATA
We consider a panel dataset consisting of 29 countries
(including advanced and emerging market economies)
between 2001 and 2014.
1
Our dependent variable is the
forecast for the budget balancetoGDP ratio, and we rely
on the projections made by WEO and Consensus
Economics.
In the case of the WEO, it has published semiannual
forecasts over the period 20012014. In both cases, the
event being forecasted is the average budget balanceto
GDP ratio for a given target year. We index the sequence
of forecasts by the horizon, H. As for Consensus Eco-
nomics, it has published monthly forecasts for major eco-
nomic variables and an increasing number of countries
on a monthly basis since 1989. For each country, the
majority of the forecasters are from the private sector,
with the number of forecasters varying between about
10 and 30. The consensusforecast is based on the
arithmetic mean of the forecasts, and we gather informa-
tion for forecasts of the budget balance for the period
January 2001December 2014.
2
Figure 1 plots the distribution of forecasts of the budget
balancetoGDP ratios for advanced and emerging coun-
tries over the sample period. We present the distribution
for horizons h= 20 (21), h= 14 (15), h= 8 (9), and h=2
(3) for WEO (Consensus). The Consensus is treated com-
paratively in an advantageous way; that is, for both cur-
rentyear and yearahead forecasts, the forecast horizon
for Consensus is 1 month later relative to WEO's.
3
At h= 20, h= 21, the distribution for both WEO and
Consensus forecasts, respectively, is centered around a
deficit of between 3% and 4% of gross domestic product
(GDP) in the case of advanced economies, but it is wider
for emerging markets (between 1% and 5% of GDP). As
the forecast horizon shortens, the distribution of forecasts
1
The list of countries included in the analysis is: advanced economies
Australia, Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, New Zealand, UK,
and USA; emerging market economiesArgentina, Brazil, Bulgaria,
China, Chile, Croatia, Czech Republic, Estonia, Hong Kong SAR, Hun-
gary, India, Latvia, Lithuania, Mexico, Poland, Russia, Slovenia, Taiwan
POC, Turkey, and Venezuela.
2
Note that Consensus started publishing forecasts of the budget balance
in 1993, but for reasons related to the perfect overlap with WEO fore-
casts we only rely on those starting in 2001.
3
Most Consensus forecasts are released at the beginning of a given
month, meaning that the information set available to private forecasters
stops 1 month before. This gives Consensus forecasts an implicit disad-
vantage by construction. Against this background, we decided to give
Consensus forecasts a 1month advantage since we are trying to argue
that, even with 1month disadvantage, WEO forecasts still add value.
Note that we have also conducted our empirical analysis by giving Con-
sensus zero advantage (i.e., using the same months for both sources) and
our results hold.
AN ET AL.651

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT