Dividend Dynamics and the Term Structure of Dividend Strips

AuthorFREDERICO BELO,ROBERT S. GOLDSTEIN,PIERRE COLLIN‐DUFRESNE
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12242
Date01 June 2015
Published date01 June 2015
THE JOURNAL OF FINANCE VOL. LXX, NO. 3 JUNE 2015
Dividend Dynamics and the Term Structure of
Dividend Strips
FREDERICO BELO, PIERRE COLLIN-DUFRESNE, and ROBERT S. GOLDSTEIN
ABSTRACT
Many leading asset pricing models are specified so that the term structure of dividend
volatility is either flat or upward sloping. These models predict that the term struc-
tures of expected returns and volatilities on dividend strips (i.e., claims to dividends
paid over a prespecified interval) are also upward sloping. However, the empirical ev-
idence suggests otherwise. This discrepancy can be reconciled if these models replace
their proposed dividend dynamics with processes that generate stationary leverage
ratios. Under such policies, shareholders are forced to divest (invest) when leverage
is low (high), which shifts risk from long- to short-horizon dividend strips.
RECENT ADVANCES IN CONSUMPTION-based asset pricing models have created an
embarrassment of riches in that several competing frameworks are now able
to capture many salient features of security prices that were once considered
puzzling (e.g., high excess returns and volatilities for stocks, low levels and
volatilities for interest rates). Due to these successes, there has been a push to
identify additional empirical moments in the hope of distinguishing between
the different frameworks. For example, recently there has been considerable
interest in the pricing and return properties of so-called dividend strips, which
are claims to dividends paid over a prespecified time interval in the future.
These assets provide information regarding the term structures of both the
Belo is with the University of Minnesota and the NBER. Collin-Dufresne is with the Swiss
Finance Institute at EPFL and the NBER. Goldstein is with the University of Minnesota and
the NBER. This paper was previously entitled “Endogenous Dividend Dynamics and the Term
Structure of Dividend Strips.” We thank the Editor, Cam Harvey, as well as the Associate Editor
and an anonymous referee for excellent suggestions. We also thank our discussants Lukas Schmid
(AFA discussant), Jakub Jurek (WFA Discussant), Ivan Shaliastovich (CAPR and NFI workshop
discussant), and Francisco Palomino (Minnesota Macro-Asset Pricing conference discussant) for
detailed comments, as well as Ravi Bansal, Jules van Binsbergen, Murray Carlson, Long Chen,
John Cochrane, Darrell Duffie, Adlai Fisher, Murray Frank, Dana Kiku, Ralph Koijen, Dimitris
Papanikolaou, Ivan Shaliastovich, Jessica Wachter,Jianfeng Yu, and seminar participants at Aalto
University/Hanken School of Economics, BI Norwegian Business School, Central Bank of Portu-
gal, Cheung Kong Graduate School of Business, Dartmouth College (Tuck), Hong Kong University,
University State Arizona (W.P. Carey), University of Pennsylvania (Wharton), University of Min-
nesota (Carlson), University of British Columbia (Sauder), University of North Carolina at Chapel
Hill (Kenan-Flagler), University of Southern California (Marshall), Vanderbilt University (Owen),
American Finance Association 2013, Western Finance Association 2012, Minnesota Macro-Asset
Pricing 2012 conference, and the 2012 CAPR/NFI workshop on Time-Varying Expected Returns
for many helpful comments. All remaining errors are our own.
DOI: 10.1111/jofi.12242
1115
1116 The Journal of Finance R
price and quantity of risk in the economy, and thus may be useful for help-
ing us understand how asset prices are determined in equilibrium. While the
return on a portfolio of all dividend strips replicates stock returns, return
characteristics of the individual strips provide an out-of-sample test for these
competing frameworks.
Indeed, while successful in capturing the asset pricing properties mentioned
above, many leading asset pricing models, such as Campbell and Cochrane
(CC, 1999), and Bansal and Yaron (BY, 2004), predict that the term structure
of expected returns and volatilities on dividend strips are strongly upward
sloping. Yet the empirical evidence reported in van Binsbergen, Brandt, and
Koijen (BBK, 2012) and van Binsbergen et al. (BHKV,2013) suggests otherwise.
Adding to the puzzle, they also report that short-horizon dividend strips possess
low CAPM market betas, high CAPM alphas, and high Sharpe ratios. While
Boguth et al. (2011)1question some of the findings in these papers, all seem to
agree that the strongly upward-sloping term structures predicted by BY and
CC are inconsistent with the historical evidence on returns of dividend strips.
Below,however, we demonstrate that the counterfactual implications of these
leading asset pricing models can be eliminated without altering their funda-
mental economic mechanisms. In particular,neither their proposed preferences
nor their consumption processes need be changed—hence, their pricing kernels
need not be altered. Instead, all that is necessary to make these models con-
sistent with many of the empirical findings of BBK is to replace their proposed
dividend dynamics with processes that are both more economically justifiable
and more consistent with the empirical properties of dividends that we identify
below. In particular, we show that the term structure of dividend volatility (i.e.,
the quantity of risk) is decreasing with horizon.2This evidence is important be-
cause, in contrast to the empirical evidence on dividend strips (for which data
are available for only a relatively short sample period), the empirical properties
of the term structure of dividend volatility can be estimated from more than a
century of data. Importantly, we show that our proposed changes to dividend
dynamics do not impact the ability of these frameworks to capture the salient
properties of stock returns mentioned previously. Intuitively, this property is
due to the dividend irrelevance argument of Modigliani and Miller (1961).
In this paper we consider dividend processes that are internally consistent
with capital structure policies that generate stationary leverage ratios. In do-
ing so, our model is able to capture two important properties that, at first blush,
seem contradictory. First, compared to unleveraged cash flows of a firm (which
we refer to as EBIT), dividends are a leveraged cash flow. It is thus not sur-
prising that claims to dividends (i.e., equity) are more volatile and have higher
average historical returns than claims to EBIT (i.e., debt plus equity). Second,
over long horizons, the dividend-EBIT ratio should be stationary,implying that
long-horizon dividends are no more volatile than long-horizon EBIT.
1See also Schulz (2013).
2Here, we are defining quantity of risk as total volatility, and not necessarily as risk that is
priced.
Dividend Dynamics and the Term Structure of Dividend Strips 1117
This apparent contradiction can be explained by noting that, when a firm
rebalances its debt levels over time to maintain a stationary leverage process,
shareholders are being forced to divest (invest) when leverage is low (high).
Thus, even if investors follow a static strategy of holding a fixed supply of stock,
their position is effectively being managed by the capital structure decisions
of the firm. Below, we show that these imposed investments/divestments con-
ceal the leveraged nature of dividends in that, even though dividends are cor-
rectly interpreted as leveraged cash flows, over the long run EBIT and divi-
dends are equally risky.
Interestingly, most leading asset pricing models ignore either the leveraged
nature of dividends or its cointegration with unleveraged cash flows (or both).
Moreover, even if they do account for leverage, they do so in a reduced-form
way by introducing free parameters that are not directly tied down to ob-
served leverage ratios. For example, for parsimony, CC specify consumption
and dividends as i.i.d. with the same drift, and therefore disregard leverage.
BY capture leverage by assuming that dividends have greater exposure to
shocks to expected growth rates than does consumption. However, their model
does not capture stationarity in the dividend-consumption ratio. Abel (1999,
2005) models cash flows to be of the form yλ, where λ=0 for fixed income se-
curities, λ=1 for EBIT, and λ>1 for dividends. Hence, this framework does
not capture stationarity in the dividend-EBIT ratio.
To demonstrate the impact of capital structure policies on the properties of
dividends in leading asset pricing models, we investigate modified versions of
the BY and CC economies. In particular, we replace their proposed dividend
processes by first specifying an unleveraged cash flow (i.e., EBIT) process (with
the same functional forms as the dividend processes in BY and CC), and then
combine it with a dynamic capital structure strategy that produces stationary
leverage ratios. These two ingredients generate an endogenously determined
dividend process that is internally consistent with the EBIT process. Claims
to this dividend process (i.e., equity) have higher expected returns and higher
volatilities than claims to EBIT (i.e., equity plus debt), yet this framework
generates a stationary dividend-EBIT ratio.
We investigate two different approaches to modeling joint dividend/leverage
dynamics. The first approach directly specifies leverage dynamics and then
identifies dividend dynamics from an accounting identity that equates the
firm’s cash inflows and outflows. Advantages of this framework are its intu-
itive nature and its tractability, as it provides analytic solutions for dividend
strip prices. Unfortunately, it generates counterfactually large correlations be-
tween short-horizon dividends and stock returns. As such, we also investigate
a second approach where dividend dynamics are directly specified and leverage
dynamics are determined from the accounting identity.In addition to matching
leverage dynamics and the term structures of dividend strips, this more flexible
framework can be calibrated to generate low CAPM betas, high CAPM alphas,
and high Sharpe ratios for the short-horizon strips, consistent with BBK and
BHKV.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT