DIVERGENCE OF OPINION AND LONG‐RUN PERFORMANCE OF PRIVATE PLACEMENTS: EVIDENCE FROM THE AUCTION MARKET

AuthorZheyao Pan,Jianlei Han,Guangli Zhang
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jfir.12170
Date01 July 2019
Published date01 July 2019
DIVERGENCE OF OPINION AND LONG-RUN PERFORMANCE OF PRIVATE
PLACEMENTS: EVIDENCE FROM THE AUCTION MARKET
Jianlei Han and Zheyao Pan
Macquarie University, Australia
Guangli Zhang
Central University of Finance and Economics, China
Abstract
In this article, we propose and construct a direct measure of investorsdivergence of opinion
based on auction bids data from private placements in China. We nd that rms with higher
bids dispersion generate lower long-run stock returns after the issuance of private
placements. This effect is economically signicant and robust when controlling for market
discount, earnings management, alternative dispersion measures, and self-selection bias.
Moreover, this negative relation is stronger for stocks with more stringent short-sale
constraints. Our ndings therefore provide strong evidence for the overvaluation hypothesis.
JEL Classification: D44, G12, G14
I. Introduction
Miller (1977) hypothesizes that divergence of opinion can lead to asset overvaluation and
subsequent market underperformance, when pessimistic investors do not take adequate
short positions, for institutional or behavioral reasons.
1
In contrast, Williamss (1977)
risk theory introduces heterogeneous beliefs into the capital asset pricing model (CAPM)
and predicts a positive relation between divergence of opinion and expected returns.
2
We are grateful to Erik Devos (editor) and an anonymous referee for their constructive comments. We also
thank Daoquan Chen, Albert Chun, Tao Gao, Xing Han, Priya Garg (discussant), Petko Kalev (discussant), Allan
Kleidon, Buhui Qiu, Byoung-Kyu Min (discussant), Krishnan Murugappa (discussant), Mohammed Sharaf
Shaiban (discussant), Tom Smith, Clara Zhou, Elizabeth Zhu, and seminar and conference participants at Xiamen
University, University of Queensland, University of Otago, University of Tasmania, Macquarie University, 2017
IFABS Asia Ningbo China Conference, 2017 FIRN Annual Conference, 2017 SIRCA Young Researchers
Workshop, 2017 Australasian Finance and Banking Conference, 2018 Financial Markets and Corporate
Governance Conference, 2018 Vietnam International Conference in Finance, and 2018 Financial Management
Association Annual Meeting for comments and suggestions. Han and Pan acknowledge funding from the
Accounting and Finance Association of Australia and New Zealand 2018 Research Grant. Zhang acknowledges
funding from the Project of Humanities and Social Science from MOE of China (18YJC790214). All remaining
errors are our own
1
As summarized by Hong and Stein (2007), three mechanisms drive divergence of opinion: gradual
information ow, limited attention, and heterogeneous priors.
2
Varian (1985) reaches the same conclusion that heterogeneous beliefs are a risk factor in the ArrowDebreu
framework. More recently, Veronesi (2000) shows that higher information quality increases expected returns,
supporting Millers (1977) hypothesis; although consistent with Williams (1977), Epstein and Schneider (2008)
prove that there is an information ambiguity premium for stocks with low information quality.
The Journal of Financial Research Vol. 0, No. 0 Pages 132 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jfir.12170
1
© 2019 The Southern Finance Association and the Southwestern Finance Association
Vol. XLII, No. 2 Pages 271302 Summer 2019
271
Using different measures of divergence, empirical studies have not generated convincing
evidence for or against Millers hypothesis in different settings. In this article, we shed
new light on this debate by proposing a novel measure of divergence of opinion based on
auction data from private placements. With this new measure, we document strong
evidence in support of Millers hypothesis.
One of the main reasons for the ambiguity am ong studies is that they use only
indirect measures for divergence of opini on (Garnkel 2009), which might overlap
with risk factors and contain substan tial measurement errors. The most co mmonly
used measure is analyst forecas t dispersion. Consistent with Mill ers (1977)
hypothesis, Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina (2002) nd that st ocks with highly
dispersed analyst forecasts have lower future ret urns than stocks with less disperse d
analyst forecasts. However, there ar e shortcomings to using analyst forec ast dispersion
to measure investorsdivergence of opinion. First, analyst dispersion is based on
forecasts of earnings rather tha n valuations. Second, investors decisions may not
follow analyst forecasts; thus, an alyst dispersion may not fully reec t market
participantsdivergence of op inion. Third, analyst dispersion i s contaminated by the
effect of uncertainty in analyst for ecasts (Barron et al. 1998; Sheng and Thev enot
2012). Fourth, analyst forecasts could be bias ed because of agency or behavioral
reasons, and investors often fail to co rrect for bias.
3
In line with these concerns,
Doukas, Kim, and Pantzalis (2006) docu ment a positive relation between divergen ce
of opinion and future returns after rem oving the effect of uncertainty in analyst
forecasts. Johnson (2004) shows tha t the ndings in Diether, Malloy, and Scherbi na
(2002) can be explained by the effect of nancial lever age. Other widely used
measures, such as idiosyncratic volat ility, turnover, unexplained trading vo lume, and
breadth of mutual fund ownership, are also ind irect proxies, which are potentially
contaminated by other return predict ors. The empirical evidence that relies on t hese
measures is mixed and inconclusive.
4
These drawbacks make it difcult to conclude whether evidence rejecting (or
supporting) Millers (1977) hypothesis is due to the theory itself or the proxy used. In this
article, we revisit Millers hypothesis and propose a direct measure of investorsopinions
regarding rm value based on their trading activities. Our measure is constructed using
auction data from private placements in China. There are two pricing schemes for private
placements in the Chinese market: a xed price set by the board of directors and a market-
clearing price from the uniform sealed auction. The former is used when the issuance
targets are internal investors, that is, controlling shareholders and blockholders. The
latter is used when the issuance targets are external investors, that is, institutional
investors including mutual funds, trusts, private funds, asset management companies,
3
See Anderson, Ghysels, and Juergens (2005, p. 899) for a review of analyst dispersion biases. In addition,
Banerjee (2011) shows that the predictive ability of analyst dispersion is sensitive to the choice of scaling factor.
4
For example, Ang et al. (2006) and Guo and Qiu (2014) nd a negative relation between idiosyncratic
volatility and returns. However, Bali and Cakici (2008) nd no robust relation between idiosyncratic volatility and
stock returns, based on different tests. Fu (2009) even documents a positive relation between these two variables
when expected idiosyncratic volatility is used. Goetzmann and Massa (2005) and Garnkel and Sokobin (2006)
reach different conclusions when trading volume is used. There is also a debate on whether turnover is a measure of
investor disagreement (Harris and Raviv 1993) or liquidity risk (Avramov and Chordia 2006).
2The Journal of Financial Research
272
and individual investors.
5
In the auction scheme, all bids information is publicly released
in private placement completion announcements. As suggested by Cammack (1991) and
Liu, Wei, and Liaw (2001), the divergence of auction bids directly reects investors
heterogeneous beliefs about valuations.
6
Therefore, this measure largely overcomes the
problems plaguing existing measures. Our measure is in line with the measure proposed
by Garnkel (2009), who uses proprietary data from investorslimit and market orders in
individual stocks to directly measure their private valuations. However, in contrast to
Garnkels measure, our auction-based measure is publicly available for a much longer
period.
7
To empirically measure investorsdivergence of opinion, we manually collect
10,425 bid records from 411 private placement auctions, from 2007 to 2015. For each
auction, we construct the dispersion of bids by two measures: quantity-weighted standard
deviationand quantity-weightedabsolute distance.We then test Millers (1977)hypothesis
by investigating the relation between the divergence of bids and private placement
investorsholding-period returns.Our sample ts Millers theoretical assumptionsbecause
most Chinese rms face stringent short-sale constraints (Chang, Luo, and Ren 2014).
In this article, we report four main empirical ndings. First, consistent with
Millers (1977) hypothesis, we nd a negative and signicant relation between the
divergence of bids and subsequent one-year stock returns for all four return measures:
two buy-and-hold abnormal return (BHAR) measures following Barber and Lyon (1997)
and Daniel et al. (1997) and two calendar-time abnormal return measures using the
CAPM and Fama and French (1993) three-factor model as benchmarks. This negative
relation is robust to controlling for the discount rate of issuing price to market price, scale
of private placement issuance, number of bidders, rm size, market-to-book ratio, cash
holding, return on assets (ROA), rm age, book leverage, earnings management, year
xed effect, and industry xed effect. In addition to statistical signicance, we nd that
the effect of bids dispersion on long-term returns is economically signicant: a one-
standard-deviation increase in the bids dispersionquantity-weighted standard
deviation (quantity-weighted absolute distance)decreases the 11-month-ahead Barber
and Lyon matched BHAR, Daniel et al. matched BHAR, CAPM-adjusted return, and
Fama and French (1993) three-factor model adjusted return by 5.05% (4.98%), 3.40%
(3.58%), 4.11% (4.29%), and 3.28% (3.30%), respectively.
Second, we test whether the predictability of bids dispersion overlaps that of the
other divergence of opinion measures in the literature. We nd that controlling for
analyst forecast dispersion, idiosyncratic volatility, and abnormal turnover does not
affect the signicance of the bids dispersion, both qualitatively and quantitatively.
Hence, our measure of bids dispersion contains new information regarding future long-
run stock returns.
5
See Section II for more details on the institutional background of private placements in China.
6
Milgrom and Webers (1982a, 1982b) generalized auction model proves that bidders have incentives to
gather extra information to increase their prots in a sealed auction.
7
Garnkel (2009) uses data from a much narrower sample period (January 2002March 2002) and does not
study the relation between his divergence of opinion measure and future stock returns.
Divergence of Opinion 3
273

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT