Distributed Generation and the Minnesota Value of Solar Tariff

Date01 August 2018
Author
48 ELR 10726 ENVIRONMENTAL LAW REPORTER 8-2018
ment of cogeneration and small power production facilities
in order to reduce demand for fossil fuels and to increase
the ecient use of energy.1 Section 210(a) directed the
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) to pro-
mulgate “such rules as it determines necessa ry to encour-
age cogeneration and small power production.” e U.S.
Supreme Court upheld a FERC rule that requires the pur-
chase rate to be “just and reasonable to the electric con-
sumers of the electric utility and in t he public interest” and
that it not discriminate against qualify ing facilities (QFs).2
e Court indicated that this framework supporting small
energy generators might not directly provide any rate sav-
ings to electric utility consumers. It was more important
to provide an incentive for small power producers and the
broader benet of decreased reliance on scarce fossil f uels
and more ecient use of energy. e Court ruled that “just
and reasonable” language in section 210(b) did not require
the rate to be set “at the lowest possible reasonable rate
consistent with the maintenance of adequate service in the
public interest,” concluding rather that Congress did not
intend to impose traditional ratemaking concepts on sales
by QFs to utilities.
In addition to established federal policy support for
distributed renewable energy, state pol icies like renewable
portfolio standards and dramatic price reductions have led
to a real-time expansion of renewable energy across the
United States. is evolution of the electricity markets
demands accommodation to dispersed renewable energy
generators. Our energy system is rapidly evolving into a
very dierent model than the legac y central station power
plant sending power one way to customers across long dis-
tance w ires. Rene wable energy deployment a nd generation
has grown rapidly and represents 25-50% of electricity
generation in many states and regions for certain periods
of time. While much of those capacity additions are from
large utility-scale projects, renewable energy production is
more geographically dispersed and variable than conven-
1. 16 U.S.C. §824 (a).
2. Am. Paper Inst. v. Am. Elec. PowerServ. Corp., 461 U.S. 402 (1983).
COMMENT
Distributed Generation and the
Minnesota Value of Solar Tariff
by Ellen Anderson
Ellen Anderson is the Executive Director of the Energy Transition Lab at the University of Minnesota.
Previously, she served in the Minnesota Senate and chaired the Minnesota Public Utilities Commission.
The Article, Managing the Future of the Electricity
Grid: Distributed Generation and Net Metering, by
Prof. Richard L. Revesz a nd Dr. Burcin Unel, is a
thorough and timely analysis of the regulatory challenges
of valuing distributed energy generation. eir proposal for
an “Avoided Cost Plus Social Benet” valuation protocol for
clean distributed energy is a va luable addition to the knowl-
edge base, and the authors’ longer-term solution of compre-
hensive energy reform is a well-thought-out alternative.
e Article establishes t hat distributed generation (DG)
provides a suite of benets to the grid and to our broader
societal goals, and it should be compensated for those ben-
ets, and that DG can a lso lead to additional costs to the
grid and can raise t he potential of cost-shifting. We appre-
ciate the approach to try to balance these factors.
e Article’s internal debate examines whether a nd how
to accurately and fairly compensate or charge d istributed
generation (DG) producers, other non-DG customers, and
utility shareholders for costs and benets of the DG sys-
tems. is is an importa nt question, but our comments are
based on a more focused set of assertions. First, pa rticularly
in markets with minimal DG, the policy reasons to incent
DG are stronger, and the cost shifting question seems pre-
mature. Second, approaches such as the Minnesota Value
of Solar Tari (VOST) are designed to nullif y cost-shifting
concerns and may serve as usef ul models.
Two underlying assumptions, consistent with Revesz
and Unel’s analysis, are important to set the stage for the
internal debate in the Article. ey a re:
(1) Federal policies generally support the concept that
more renewable, distribute d generation i s benecia l
and in the public interest.
(2) Changes to our electricity resource mix demand
that grid operators and utilities integrate vari-
able renewable resources produced by many dis-
persed generators.
On point one, the Public Utilities Regulatory Policy Act
(PURPA) includes a clear statement to encourage develop-
Copyright © 2018 Environmental Law Institute®, Washington, DC. Reprinted with permission from ELR®, http://www.eli.org, 1-800-433-5120.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT