Did Copenhagen Give Climate Change Legislation Any 'Bounce' in the Senate?

Date01 March 2010
Author
40 ELR 10248 ENVIRONMENTAL LAW REPORTER 3-2010
Did Copenhagen Give Climate
Change Legislation Any
“Bounce” in the Senate?
by Tom Mounteer
Tom Mounteer is a partner in the Washington, D.C., oce of Paul Hastings,
where he co-chairs the law rm’s environmental practice. Since 1997, he has
been an adjunct professor in the Masters in Environmental Law program at the
George Washington University Law School. He is also author of the Climate
Change Deskbook (Envtl. L. Inst. 2009). He thanks Paul Hastings Washington
oce associate Jennifer Shea for her contribution to this column.
If President Barack Obama expected
to get any “bounce” f rom Dec em-
ber’s i nternat ional climate change
talks in Copenh agen in terms of
gain ing U.S. Senate accepta nce of
comprehen sive cli mate cha nge legis-
lation, he must have been sorely dis-
appointed. Of course, afte r hi s rec ent
State of t he Union address —with its
focus on domestic jobs—perhaps the
president’s clim ate chang e ambitions
are d iminished.
During the State of the Union
address, the president did laud the U.S.
House of Representatives’ passage of t he
Waxman-Markey cap-and-trade bill.1
Certain passages in his address were
deant in their ref usal to sca le back his
ambition despite the trying times.
e fundamental problem the presi-
dent confronts with respect to cap-and-
trade legislation, however, is that the
biggest politica l “k nocks” against it go
right to the hear t of his domestic jobs
agenda. Opponents of cap-and-trade
legislation deride it as disastrous for
the economy and as incentivizing the
export of U.S. jobs.
Copenhagen oered little to over-
come these vulnerabilities.
If not an outright op, the so-called
Copenhagen Accord was certainly no
blockbus ter. Not a le gally bind ing
agr eeme nt, the delegate s settle d on
a “not e.”
Even if the Oba ma Administra-
tion had realistic expectations for the
talks, one presumes the Ad ministration
would like to have gotten some sort of
“bounce” from the talks to persuade
an increasingly reluctant Senate to
support cap-and-trade legislation. e
media were certa inly stirred up by the
prospects of 119 heads of state gather-
ing. President Obama not only made
the trip, but he also promised that the
United States would achieve greenhouse
gas (GHG) emissions reductions equiv-
alent to those contained in the Wax-
man-Markey Bill. He pledged to cut
U.S. emissions “ in the range of” 17%
by 2020 from 2005 levels.
It seems unlikely that Copenhagen
will provide any “bounce” at all. ere
are a number of reasons for that. First,
there is little in the Copenhagen Accord
likely to appease those Democratic sen-
ators who have opposed cap-and-trade
legislation because of its eects on the
U.S. economy and jobs. Second, sena-
tors may be skeptical of the integrity
of the promises that developing coun-
tries, especially China, made under the
Accord. ird, in this sour economy,
there may be little Senate appetite to
fund the adoption of GHG-reducing
technologies overseas.
Beyond the overall costs that cap-
and-trade legislation is projected to
impose on the troubled economy, sena-
torial reticence stems from a concern
that capping domestic GHG emissions
will cause industry to relocate overseas
where they would not face such caps
(or the costs of acquiring allowances)—
taking U.S. jobs with them. Before
President Obama left for Copenhagen,
10 Democratic senators expressed con-
cerns along these lines in two letters
to the president. e senators warned
that any international climate agree-
ment must ensure a level playing eld
for U.S. companies and workers. ey
cautioned aga inst shifting GHG emis-
sions—and underlying jobs—to coun-
tries t hat refuse to take actions similar
to the United States.
e most frequently touted mecha-
nism to prevent emissions and job
leakage abroad is the so-called border
adjustment mechanism—essentia lly
a tari on imports from countries not
enforcing GHG caps. e Waxman-
Markey Bill includes a border adjust-
ment mechanism, i.e., the “international
reserve allowance” program, beginning
in 2020 if energy-intensive, trade-sensi-
tive sectors in the United States are still
impacted by international competitive-
ness issues.2
e mechanism is controversial.
Experts call its legality under interna-
tional free trade agreements into ques-
tion. It risks triggering retaliation from
aected countries. China, for example,
has rai led against the border adjust-
ment concept.
In addition to international trade
and competitiveness concerns, senators
remain skeptical about the promises
developing countries made under the
Copenhagen Accord. Prior to Copen-
hagen, China pledged to reduce its “car-
bon intensity”—not its absolute GHG
emissions—by 40 to 45% below 2005
levels. In other words, China plans to
continue to grow its economy but to do
so in a more energy-ecient manner.
Of course, those with a long-ter m
perspective point to the prog ress that
any commitment from developing
countrie s to re ducing carbon emis-
Tom Mounteer
Copyright © 2010 Environmental Law Institute®, Washington, DC. reprinted with permission from ELR®, http://www.eli.org, 1-800-433-5120.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT