The devil is in the details: How arbitration system design and training facilitate and inhibit repeat‐player advantages in private and state‐run arbitration hearings

AuthorPeter C. Alter,Shauhin A. Talesh
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/lapo.12155
Date01 October 2020
Published date01 October 2020
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
The devil is in the details: How arbitration system
design and training facilitate and inhibit repeat-
player advantages in private and state-run
arbitration hearings
Shauhin A. Talesh | Peter C. Alter
Irvine School of Law, University of California, Irvine, CA, USA
Correspondence
Shauhin A. Talesh, Professor of Law,
Sociology and Criminology, Law & Society,
University of California, IrvineSchool of
Law, 401 E. Peltason Drive, Ste. 3500F, Irvine,
CA 92697, USA.
Email: stalesh@law.uci.edu
Funding information
National Science Foundation, Grant/Award
Number: SES-0919874
[The copyright line for this article was changed
on 08 March 2021 after original online
publication]
Abstract
This article demonstrates that arbitration system design
and the training that arbitrators receive shape the extent to
which repeat players gain advantages in arbitration hear-
ings. While prior arbitration research does suggest that
arbitrator training matters, this is the first article to show
how it matters, as we observe actual arbitration hearings
in private and state-run arbitration systems in two states.
Our comparative analysis links three literatures interested
in how seemingly interest-neutral institutions, like disput-
ing forums, serve in practice to reinforce dominant norms,
values, and hierarchies: (1) sociolegal studies of repeat-
player advantages in disputing, (2) studies of occupational
socialization in educational settings, and (3) neoinstitutional
organizational sociology studies of how managerial values
influence the way in which organizations construct law.
We bridge these literatures by showing how arbitrator sys-
tem design and the occupational socialization that arbitra-
tors receive in private arbitration are primary mechanisms
through which managerial values influence the arbitration
process, ultimately providing a pathway for repeat-player
advantages in hearings. Because our analysis compares
two distinct arbitration systems, we identify variation in
these processes and offer preliminary but tangible policy
recommendations for the design and implementation of
arbitration systems that best protect civil and consumer
rights within arbitral forums that the Supreme Court con-
tinually upholds.
DOI: 10.1111/lapo.12155
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivs License, which permits
use and distribution in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited, the use is non-commercial and no modifications or
adaptations are made.
©2020 The Authors. Law & Policy published by University of Denver/Colorado Seminary and Wiley Periodicals LLC.
Law & Policy. 2020;42:315343. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/lapo 315
Given the recent and dramatic expansion of disputes being heard outside courts and, in partic u-
lar, the role of arbitration in the American legal system, scholars have labored to under-
stand the consequences of favoring arbitration over courts. This endeavor, gaining real
urgency in the 1980s with benchmark Supreme Court decisions approving arbitrations
expansion, has developed today into a robust literature, much of it focusing on the ways in
which arbitration may serve to favor repeat players”—that is, regulars in the forumover
one-shotters,who are unlikely to make use of the forum more than once, potentially
exacerbating a phenomenon identified in the courts (Galanter 1974). These studies gener-
ally focus on particular facets of a single arbitral system or comparative analyses of a par-
ticular arbitral forum and the courts.
But scholarship comparing different arbitration systems to one another is strikingly
absent from this discussion (cf. Chandrasekher and Horton 2019). This gap is significant
for two reasons. First, there is no single system of arbitration. Unlike the court system with
its standardized rules and procedures, each arbitration system takes its own stance on myr-
iad issues of design, procedure, and evidence, resulting in a diverse array of dispute resolu-
tion structures all falling under the nominal umbrella of arbitration.Insofar as the
existing scholarship focuses on differences between courts and arbitration and outcomes
within single arbitration systems, it has largely failed to assess the impact that variation
between arbitration systems might have on the substantive rights claimed therein and the
extent to which repeat playersare advantaged over one-shottersin a given forum
(Galanter 1974). Second, there is no reason to think that a shift away from arbitrations
expanded role is on the horizon given the Supreme Courts recent decisions and the current
political climate. For better or worse, the expanded role of arbitration appears unlikely to
change in the near future (Glover 2015).
Given the expanded role of arbitration in the American legal system and the diverse array
of dispute resolution structures encompassed by the label arbitration,it is imperative to
understand how best to protect the efficacy of civil and consumer rights within different arbitral
forums in which repeat players often hold advantages (Galanter 1974). Thus, in this article, we
seek to answer the following question: how do different arbitration system designs and the
training that arbitrators receive to implement those systems facilitate or inhibit repeat-player
advantages in arbitration hearings?
To answer this question, we undertook an analysis of arbitration hearings in California
and Vermont, which involved substantively similar consumer warranty lemonlaws but
substantially disparate arbitration designs. Californias lemon law allows disputes to be
resolved in dispute resolution forums funded by automobile manufacturers but operated by
external third-party organizations. By contrast, in Vermont, consumer disputes are resolved
using a public arbitration structure operated by the state alone. In California, a single arbi-
trator, trained by the third-party provider using a uniform system and typically without a
background in the automotive industry, adjudicates the dispute. In Vermont, a five-
member board made up of a technical expert, an automobile dealer, and three citizen mem-
bers adjudicates the dispute, having received little to no formal training. The systems adopt
different models of justice and different approaches to procedural nuances. B y analyzing
these disparate systems arbitrating substantially similar consumer protection laws, we are
able to best identify the differences in system design and arbitrator training that facilitate
or inhibit repeat-player advantages. We gained access to and observed fifty-seven hearings
in both states, analyzing hearing transcripts where available and contemporaneous field
notes where they were not.
Selecting these forums for our analysis also allows us to build upon the limited existing liter-
ature comparing arbitration systems. Talesh (2012) undertook a comparative analysis and
found that these different arbitration systems give different meanings to substantially similar
lemon laws operating in both states, and that this is due largely to the way that business and
316 ARBITRATORTRAININGAND DESIGN IMPACTON HEARINGS

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT