Developments in Vertical Agreements

Published date01 December 2010
DOI10.1177/0003603X1005500407
Date01 December 2010
AuthorNikolaos Vettas
Subject MatterArticle
Developments in
vertical agreements
BYNIKOLAOS VETTAS*
This article discusses issues related to vertical agreements. I focus on
recent developments in the treatment of such agreements by
European Commission competition law, including the new vertical
agreements Block Exempt Regulation and the accompanying
Guidelines that came into effect in June of 2010. The main structure of
the old Regulation has been maintained. The general direction of the
changes in the Regulation and especially in the Guidelines is in line
with a more effects-based and economics-based approach to
competition policy that has been adopted gradually in the EC over
the last decade as well as with the developments in the United States
concerning the treatment of resale price maintenance. However, since
it is extremely unlikely that vertical agreements that involve only
firms with small market shares will have an anticompetitive effect,
the adoption of a de minimis approach for all vertical agreements
appears advisable for the future.
THE ANTITRUST BULLETIN:Vol. 55, No. 4/Winter 2010 :843
* Professor, Department of Economics, Athens University of Economics
and Business; Research Fellow, Centre for Economic Policy Research, UK; and
Member of the Economic Advisory Group in Competition Policy, European
Commission, DG-Competition.
AUTHOR’S NOTE: I am grateful to the editor of this special issue, Ioannis Kokkoris, for
his guidance and comments. I am solely responsible for the exposition of the
arguments here.
© 2010 by Federal Legal Publications, Inc.
I. INTRODUCTION
Vertical relations have received increasingly more attention from the
view point of competition policy over the last years. One reason is
that buyers, as well as sellers, in many important markets are
becoming larger and increasing their market power. The vertical
agreements reached between such sellers and buyers will play a cru-
cial role in determining the market outcome in the final market and
the welfare of the final consumers. A second reason is that the verti-
cal agreements used have become increasingly complex and varied
in nature—details in such agreements can often make an important
difference. A third reason, in part a result of the first two develop-
ments, is that there is increasing recognition among policy makers
that most—if not all—types of such agreements are neither com-
pletely procompetitive nor completely anticompetitive and that
there should be an economics-based evaluation of their implications
for the markets and the consumers. Thus, we are moving (albeit
only gradually) away from a more formalistic approach that often
appears de facto to support the per se legality or illegality of certain
types of agreements.
In this article, I discuss some of the fundamental economic issues
relating to vertical agreements, focusing on their treatment by Article
101 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU),
that is, agreements between “upstream” and “downstream” firms
that do not necessarily have a dominant position in their markets. In
particular, I discuss the new Block Exemption Regulation applicable
to vertical agreements that has recently been adopted by the Euro-
pean Commission and the new accompanying Guidelines. Both
entered into force on June 1, 2010. I also relate the approach to these
vertical agreements to the approaches followed by other aspects of
competition law and policy and place them in the broader context of
an economics approach. Finally, I suggest that the recent revision of
the Block Exemption Regulation (BER) and the Guidelines, while
moving in the right direction, have not reached far enough. In partic-
ular, I believe that it should have been recognized in the Regulation
that it is extremely unlikely—and probably impossible—that there is
harm in the market and to consumers as a result of any type of verti-
cal agreement if all the firms involved have a small enough market
844 :THE ANTITRUST BULLETIN:Vol. 55, No. 4/Winter 2010
share, thus essentially favoring a de minimis approach to such agree-
ments. Perhaps, such an approach can be adopted in the future.
The remainder of the article is structured as follows. Section II
reviews the relevant legislation and recent changes in regulation and
the law applicable to vertical relations. Section III presents a quick
introduction to the main economic analysis of vertical relations,
explaining the reasons that will make firms engage in some particular
form of vertical trade and the positive and negative implications for
competition policy. In section IV we turn our attention to the new
BER applicable to vertical agreements in the EC and the new accom-
panying Guidelines. In section V, I present a critical evaluation of this
new BER, examining both its positive aspects and also areas where
additional improvement relative to the old Regulation could have
been possible. Parts of this evaluation draw upon the relevant opin-
ion submitted to the Commission by the ad hoc subgroup of the Eco-
nomic Advisory Group in Competition Policy. Section VI concludes.
II. VERTICAL RELATIONS AND EC COMPETITION POLICY
A. The nature of vertical relations
Vertical relations refer to the relationships between firms that
trade with each other along a “chain” that moves from upstream
(further away from the final consumer) to downstream (closer to the
final consumer). These firms are typically suppliers of goods (or
services) and their distributors (wholesalers and retailers) and, more
generally, sellers and buyers when the buyers are not the final
consumers but purchase intermediate goods for further processing or
distribution. In some cases, the firms involved may choose to proceed
to a vertical merger. In other cases, the firms maintain their
independence. Trade between them may then take a simple form in
which a single unit price is arranged (constant per unit of quantity
sold, or linear pricing) or the relationship may be a more complex
one, in which case the need arises in competition policy to study
these vertical agreements more carefully. These include more
elaborate pricing schemes, such as two-part tariffs, quantity discounts
(or other such forms of nonlinear pricing), royalties and rebates, other
forms of vertical restraint, such as resale price maintenance (RPM)
VERTICAL AGREEMENTS :845

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT