Demographic change and long‐term growth in China: Past developments and the future challenge of aging

Published date01 August 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12405
AuthorMin Zhao,Pei‐Ju Liao,Minchung Hsu
Date01 August 2018
SPECIAL ISSUE ARTICLE
Demographic change and long-term growth in
China: Past developments and the future challenge
of aging
Minchung Hsu
1
|
Pei-Ju Liao
2
|
Min Zhao
3
1
National Graduate Institute for Policy
Studies, Tokyo, Japan
2
Department of Economics, National
Taiwan University, Taipei, Taiwan
3
World Bank Beijing Office, Beijing,
China
Correspondence
Minchung Hsu, National Graduate
Institute for Policy Studies, Tokyo, Japan
Email: minchunghsu@gmail.com
Funding information
GRIPS Policy Research Center; Nomura
Foundation; JSPS KAKENHI; National
Science Council, Grant/Award Number:
20467062; 16KK0052; 17H02537; NSC
100-2410-H-001-026-MY2
Abstract
This paper explores the influence of demographic changes,
particularly the sharp decline in fertility and the evolution of
the population age structure, on economic development in
China. A general equilibrium overlapping generations model
with endogenous decisions on fertility, educational invest-
ment, and factor accumulation is employed for our analysis.
The family support provided by children to the elderly, which
is a component of traditional culture in Chinese society, is
also considered. We find that technological changes matter
most for growth. Demographic changes, on average, account
for approximately 4% of the growth in China, while the effect
is negative in the pre-1980 period. With an extension to
include population aging, we find that aging is not necessarily
adverse to growth. This finding reflects the fact that a longer
life expectancy requires more savings and makes educational
investment in children more attractive, which accelerates
physical capital and human capital accumulation. However, if
the social norm of family support for aging parents is strict,
aging will significantly increase the childrens burden and
crowd out physical and human capital accumulation.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
China has experienced rapid economic growth in the past three decades, particularly following its
market-oriented economic reform. Figure 1 shows the per capita GDP of China during the period
from 1952 to 2014. China experienced stagnation in the 1950s and 1960s and significant growth
since the early 1980s.
DOI: 10.1111/rode.12405
928
|
©2018 John Wiley & Sons Ltd wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/rode Rev Dev Econ. 2018;22:928952.
Chinas high economic growth has been associated with a sharp decline in fertility. As Figure 2
shows, the total fertility rate (TFR, number of children per woman) in the 1950s and 1960s was
above 6 (disregarding the drought period from 1959 to 1965). The TFR rapidly declined to fewer
than 3 children at the implementation of the one-child policy and remained between 1 and 2 after
1990.
The decline in fertility reduces the dependency ratio in China. Figure 3 shows that the total
dependency ratio in China has sharply declined since the 1980s. Labor quality also greatly
improved during the same period, as shown in Figure 4. The literature on the demographic transi-
tion and economic growth has documented the quantityquality trade-off mechanism for children
and discussed the benefit of lower fertility in the early stage of development.
1
The aforemen-
tioned figures also suggest a similar pattern in China. Therefore, in addition to productivity
growth and factor accumulation, it is natural to ask how important demographic change is for
Chinas growth.
2
This paper takes a structural approach. We first develop a structural model that is consistent
with certain main economic/demographic features and the pattern of the quantityquality trade-off
of children in China to quantify the importance of the demographic transition in Chinas develop-
ment. Although the total dependency ratio has largely declined since 1970, China will soon have
to confront population aging due to the low fertility rate and extended longevity. Figure 5 plots
the projected old-age dependency ratio up to 2100 in China. The old-age dependency ratio will
increase by a factor of 5, from approximately 10% in 2010 to 50% in 2100. The impacts of aging
on the economy are at least threefold. First, the proportion of the working-age population will
decline, which reduces the labor supply. Second, increased savings are required for a longer retire-
ment life. Third, the extended longevity may affect the incentives for education investment. There-
fore, this paper also investigates the potential impact of rapid aging on Chinas future
development.
A general equilibrium overlapping generations model with endogenous decisions on fertility,
education investment, and factor accumulation is employed for a structural analysis.
3
Given the
Chinese culture and social norms, adult children are expected to support their retired parents. To
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010
0
2000
4000
6000
8000
10000
12000
GDP per capita
FIGURE 1 GDP per capita in China [Color figure can be viewed at wileyonlinelibrary.com]
Source: Penn World Table version 9.0. The series of real GDP at constant national prices (2011 US dollars) and
population are used to compute the per capita GDP.
HSU ET AL.
|
929

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT