Demand for nondurable goods: a shortcut to estimating long‐run price elasticities

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12194
Published date01 August 2017
Date01 August 2017
AuthorHelena Perrone
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.48, No. 3, Fall 2017
pp. 856–873
Demand for nondurable goods: a shortcut
to estimating long-run price elasticities
Helena Perrone
When consumers stockpile, static demand models overestimate long-term price responses. This
article presents a dynamic model of demand with consumer inventories and proposes a shortcut
to estimate the long-run price elasticities without having to solve the dynamic program. Using
French data on food purchases, I find elasticities consistent with those that result from the
full-blown estimations found in the literature.
1. Introduction
Standard demand models assume that consumers, purchase choices are static (see, e.g.,
Berry, Levinsohn, and Pakes, 1995; and Nevo, 2001; among many others). However, there is
substantial empirical evidence that in a number of products, consumers stockpile (e.g., Boizot,
Robin, and Visser, 2001; Hendel and Nevo, 2006a). When this is the case, ignoring dynamics
may lead to upward-biased estimates of long-run demand price elasticities, because a static
model captures not only the effect of prices on consumption but also the short-term variation in
inventories (Hendel and Nevo, 2006a, 2006b).
To deal with these issues, we need to estimate a dynamic model, but this can be costly
because estimation of a dynamic demand model usually requires solving a dynamic programming
problem, which is a computer time-consuming numerical exercise. However, because for most
policy purposes, for example, competition policy, we require long-run elasticities, it is important
to develop techniques to estimate long-run effects without completely solving the dynamic
programming problem. This article contributes to the literature by proposing a simple procedure
to estimate long-run own-price elasticities that does not require solving the value function. My
method, although simple, is flexible with respect to consumer heterogeneity, price processes, and
consumers’ future price expectations. Note that the model in its current format does not address
brand differentiation, hence, I can estimate long-run own-price elasticities, but not cross-price
elasticities.
In the model, consumers maximize their discounted utility flow by choosing, in each period,
how much to purchase, how much to consume, and how much to leave as inventory of a single
Universitat Pompeu Fabraand Barcelona GSE; helena.perrone@upf.edu.
I would like to thank Larbi Alaoui, Steven Berry,Christian Brownlees, Jan Eeckhout, Juanjo Ganuza, Christian Michel,
Aviv Nevo, Vincent Requillart, and Michael Waterson for helpful comments. I would also like to thank anonymous
referees whose comments and suggestions greatly improved the article. I am especially grateful to Pierre Dubois for
his encouragement, guidance, and support throughout this work. Research support by CAPES and INRA is kindly
acknowledged. All errors are mine.
856 C2017, The RAND Corporation.
PERRONE / 857
homogeneous product. Future prices are uncertain. In the model, when prices are high relative to
expected future prices, consumers only purchase to cover current consumption, not to stockpile.
Consumers purchase and store at discounted prices, using stocks to avoid having to purchase
at high prices. If storage were costless and there was no discounting, they would buy their
lifetime consumption when the price is at its lowest. However,storage is costly. Thus, consumers
hold limited stocks that they supplement when prices are low and deplete when prices are high,
purchasing at nonsale prices only if there is not enough of the product in storage to cover current
consumption. Therefore, in periods of high prices, the purchase decision depends on how much
of the product consumers already have in stock and on consumption at current prices.
I propose to use these properties of the model to simplify estimation. In particular, the
key to the simplicity of the method is twofold. First, I estimate parameters when choices are
not affected by future expected variables that require solving the value function. Second, I only
require current observable variables and the beginning-of-the-period inventory level, which I
am able to construct from the panel data. Note that restricting the estimation sample does not
create a selection problem under the standard assumption that the marginal utility of income is
independent of the price level.
The empirical implementation requires an assumption concerning how consumers form fu-
ture price expectations, a utility function specification, and an assumption regarding consumption
out of stock. However, the methodology is quite flexibleand allows for various alternative assump-
tions. In the application, I consider a constant absolute risk aversion (CARA) utility specification
and three alternative price expectation formation hypotheses. The first assumes that consumers
always expect prices to return to their regular (mean) level, whereas the second and third price
expectation formation hypotheses assume different first-order Markov processes.
With respect to consumption out of stock (consumption in periods when the consumer
does not purchase the product but still consumes it), I assume that it depends on the expected
replacement costs, which I proxy by the average price paid for each unit in stock. I empirically
check the sensitivity of the results to this assumption by estimating the model in subsamples with
increasingly shorter interpurchase periods. The shorter the interpurchase periods, the less I have
to assume the out-of-stock level of consumption. Furthermore, I also estimate parameters in a
subsample that includes only purchases made at high prices following periods of purchases at
high prices. This means that in this subsample, inventories are always zero (at the beginning and
end of each period) and consumption equals purchases in each period. Parameter identification
therefore does not require the use of the out-of-stock consumption assumption because, according
to the model, consumers never consume from stock in this subsample.
The model is estimated using French homescan data on food products overthree years (1999,
2000, 2001). In the data, each observation is a purchase occasion, and I observe exactly what
was purchased, when it was purchased, and the price paid. The empirical analysis is performed
considering five different product categories: butter, coffee, milk, pasta, and yogurt. Note that in
contrast to the United States, the most common type of milk in France is shelf-stable ultrapasteur-
ized (UHT) milk. It represents more than 97% of French milk consumption (Institut Professionnel
du Lait de Consommation, www.iplc.fr). It can be stored on shelves for a long time whileclosed
and for approximately one week in a refrigerated area once opened. This is the type of milk I
consider in the sample, not fresh milk.
Consistent with previous results in the literature, the estimation results show that the price
elasticities yielded by a static model that ignores inventories consistently overestimate long-run
responses. The bias ranges from 20% up to more than 100%. The magnitudes of my long-run price
elasticity estimates are also consistent with previous literature estimates obtained by solving the
complete dynamic programming model, which is further evidence supporting my method (see,
e.g., Sun, Neslin, and Srinivasan, 2003; Sun, 2005; Hartmann and Nair, 2009; Hendel and Nevo,
2006b, 2013). (Note that these articles focus on different products and, as expected, numbers are
similar but not identical.) The results are robust to the assumption on consumption out of stock,
to the estimation method, and to the price expectation hypothesis (although the results are more
C
The RAND Corporation 2017.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT