Decentralizing Pork: Congressional Roll‐Call Voting, Decentralized Administration, and Distributive Politics

Published date01 February 2018
AuthorAnthony M. Bertelli,Pamela J. Clouser McCann
Date01 February 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/lsq.12183
ANTHONY M. BERTELLI
New York University
PAMELA J. CLOUSER McCANN
University of Southern California
Decentralizing Pork:
Congressional Roll-Call Voting,
Decentralized Administration, and
Distributive Politics
Congress packages pork-barrel spending in complicated proposals that belie theo-
ries of distributive politics. We theorize that roll-call voting on such bills depends on
grant programs’ administrative centralization, party ties with presidents or home-state
governors, and differences in geographic representation between chambers. Analyzing
votes between 1973 and 2010 using a within-legislator strategy reveals that House mem-
bers are less likely to support decentralized spending when they are copartisans with
presidents, while senators support decentralization regardless of such party ties. When
House members or senators share affiliation with only governors or with neither chief
executive, the likelihood of support rises with decentralization.
Understanding how government programs are designed and imple-
mented as well as how they distribute resources is vital to the study of
politics and public policy. Congressional scholars argue that legislators
have a compelling incentive to vote in favor of bringing federal dollars to
their districts and states (e.g., Balla et al. 2002; Baron 1991; Cox and
McCubbins 2005; Evans 1994; Shepsle and Weingast 1981). Although
many Americans decry the principle of earmarks, most voters prefer
legislators who bring government projects and dollars home to their dis-
tricts, putting local above national interests (see generally Drake 2013;
Miller 2016; Pew Research Center 2010). Indeed, voters may use federal
spending in their district or state as a proxy when assessing a legislator’s
competence (Grimmer, Messing, and Westwood 2012; Lazarus 2010).
Previous work on distributive politics focuses on the funds districts
receive rather than the legislation on which members vote. While tar-
geted spending is attractive, distributive bills are often complicated, and
to our knowledge, we provide the f‌irst large-scale study of votes on
LEGISLATIVE STUDIES QUARTERLY, 43, 1, February 2018 69
DOI: 10.1111/lsq.12183
V
C2017 Washington University in St. Louis
them. Targeted funds and earmarks are straightforward mechanisms for
bringing dollars to constituents, yet bills are rarely crafted using them
alone. Lee draws our attention to “the many ways that pork can be pack-
aged” (2004, 205), such as formula, block, categorical, and
demonstration project grants, not to mention contracts, loans, and other
means (Miller 2016; Salamon 2002). A voluminous literature has devel-
oped around the politics of distributive spending and the factors
associated with the ability to bring home federal dollars, but studies of
federal outlays focus on how administrators distribute programmatic dol-
lars, rather than how legislators voted on the bills that provided the
underlying authorizations.
1
In parallel studies of legislative coalition for-
mation, scholars argue that members of the majority party, senators from
smaller and less populous states, or House members from more populous
states are rewarded with more federal resources (e.g., Ansolabehere,
Snyder, and Ting 2003; Knight 2008; Lee 2000). These studies implicitly
assume that all legislators who benef‌it from funds would vote in favor of
bills authorizing them, and our study challenges this assumption.
Members frequently vote against spending that may benef‌it their
constituents and must justify such decisions, as in the case of Rep. Heath
Shuler (D-NC) and the 2009 economic stimulus package: “I didn’t vote
for it, but that doesn’t mean that I don’t support western North Carolina
getting its fair share” (Thrush 2009). Transportation bills, for example,
often incorporate district- and state-level distributive programs (Lee
2004), yet not every member votes in favor of f‌inal passage, even when
his or her district would benef‌it. What explains these voting choices?
Current theories fail to capture the conditions under which members
oppose laws offering federal spending in their districts (but see Sellers
1997). Given that districts would see these funds months, if not years, in
the future,
2
we make the important observations that (1) provisions
decentralizing federal programs shift inf‌luence from federal to state off‌i-
cials and (2) members are concerned about the distributional
consequences of such delegation choices and (3) vote accordingly.
We offer a theory that roll-call voting on bills with grant programs
depends on the level of administrative centralization of those programs,
party ties between a member and the president or home state governor,
and the differences in geographic representation between chambers.
When members vote on legislation, they also vote on the degree to
which administration is centralized with federal agencies or decentral-
ized to the states (McCann 2016).
3
Decentralized provisions create an
additional administrative layer between members and their constituents
that impacts the costs of ex post oversight. Centralized provisions, by
contrast, leave administration in the hands of a federal agency. We argue
70 Anthony M. Bertelli and Pamela J. Clouser McCann
that time-constrained legislators understand that they must spend their
scarce resources to ensure that their districts receive federal dollars and
that sharing partisan aff‌iliation with the president or home state governor
can moderate the ex post costs associated with overseeing the distribu-
tion of funds to constituents. Moreover, while senators can claim credit
for any decentralized funds because their constituencies are statewide,
House members must still ensure that funds administered at the state
level reach their districts.
Using correlated random effects statistical models that account for
unobservable attributes of legislators, we analyze a unique data set of
30,005 coded provisions and associated roll-call votes in the House and
Senate from 199 major laws enacted during the 93d to 111th Congresses
(1973–2010). Within-member designs such as ours are common in the
contemporary literature on pork-barrel politics (Alexander, Berry, and
Howell 2014; Berry and Fowler 2016). Beyond ideology, committee
membership, seniority, prior electoral margins, and other characteristics
that have been found to be signif‌icant in studies of pork-barrel politics
(see Grose 2011, 202–03), legislators represent different groups of con-
stituents, which exert different pressures on their votes, suggesting the
importance of legislator-level designs to account for this heterogeneity.
Our design further accounts for unobserved heterogeneity by state, con-
gress, and policy domain, insulating our hypothesis tests from a variety
of inf‌luences over pork-barrel spending on both the supply and demand
side (e.g., Bertelli and Grose 2009; Stein and Bickers 1995). We f‌ind
House members less likely to support proposals with decentralized
administration when they share partisanship with the president alone or
also with homestate governors. When House members and senators are
copartisans with only their governors or with neither chief executive, the
likelihood of support rises with decentralization. Our theory and results
suggest a new way of viewing distributive politics in policy formation
with a host of important implications for our understanding of
partisanship and administrative design on congressional voting.
A Theory of Members’ Voting Choices on Federal
Distributive Programs
We begin our argument with two reasonable assumptions. First,
we assume legislators care about re-election. Second, we assume that
individual members of Congress are time constrained in their legislative
activities (Hall 1987, 1996), which restricts the extent to which they can
oversee when and how funds are deployed to their states and districts.
For existing programs and policies, members of Congress spend
71Decentralizing Pork

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT