Damages

AuthorJohn Fabian Witt
Pages635-714
CHAPTER 10. DAMAGES
O reader, to what shifts is poor Society reduced, struggling
to give still some account of herself, in epochs when Cash
Payment has become the sole nexus of man to men!
Thomas Carlyle, Chartism 61 (1840)
The ones showing up in court demanding justice, all
they’ve got their eye on’s that million dollar price tag.
It’s not simply the money no . . . . because the money’s
just a yardstick isn’t it. It’s the only common reference
people have for making other people take them as seriously
as they take themselves.
William Gaddis, A Frolic of His Own (1994)
So far in this book we have paid little attention to the endgame for torts claims. But of
course that will not do at all. Plaintiffs in tort suits bring claims to accomplish
something. Lawsuits are expensive and time consuming. Being in one can be a
miserable experience. (After a dozen years of watching litigation from the bench, the
great torts jurist Learned Hand remarked that “as a litigant I should dread a lawsuit
beyond almost anything else short of sickness and death.” Gerald Gunther, Learned
Hand: The Man and the Judge 122 (2d ed. 2010).)
Why, then, do plaintiffs assert claims? The reasons are many. But one thing we
can say for certain is that in the United States, the remedy in a successful tort suit is
virtually always the payment of damages, measured in dollars. Courts do not, for
example, require public apologies, or acts of service to the decedent’s family, or jail time
for the tortfeasor. Instead, the stated aim of damages in tort is to order money damages
sufficient to restore the plaintiff to his or her prior state.
Of course, this aspiration immediately begs more questions than it answers. Can
money ever restore the status quo ante? The notion is especially challenging in cases
involving the loss of life or limb. And what does it mean to treat money as a kind of
equivalent to such losses? Thomas Carlyle, a forceful nineteenth century English critic of
the market, objected that the “cash nexus” impoverished social relations among men.
Like-minded critics today observe that the regime of money damages risks
commodifying things like life and health that we would never allow to be sold in the
marketplace. (Some go on to note too the inequalities that can result from making the
market our measure of value.)
10. Damages
636
The criticisms of money damages have great weight. And yet there is also
something extraordinary about money damages. In a liberal society in which we choose
our own values, in which each person gets to decide what matters to herself, money
serves as a common currency of value, connecting people with radically different values.
The oenophile may not share the same priorities as the NASCAR fan. The bridge player
may not see the world in the same fashion as the BASE jumper. But dollars translate
their divergent interests into a common coin. Cash, one might say, is the lingua franca
the Esperanto -- of liberal value pluralism.
Or so the beginnings of a defense of money damages might run. The critics will
likely remain unmollified. And yet there is no gainsaying the centrality of money
damages in the law and social practice of damages in American tort law.
A. Compensatory Damages
Given that money is the currency in which tort damages are paid, how do courts figure
out how much money is required? The law typically treats compensatory damages as
coming in two flavors: pecuniary damages, on the one hand, and nonpecuniary, on the
other. Pecuniary damages aim to reproduce the amount of money lost by the plaintiff,
typically because of lost income and increased expenditures. The calculation, however, is
not always as easy as it might seem.
1. Pecuniary Damages
O’Shea v. Riverway Towing Co., 677 F.2d 1194 (7th Cir. 1982)
POSNER, J.
On the day of the accident, Margaret O'Shea was coming off duty as a cook on a
towboat plying the Mississippi River. A harbor boat operated by the defendant, Riverway
Towing Company, carried Mrs. O'Shea to shore and while getting off the boat she fell
and sustained the injury complained of. The district judge found Riverway negligent and
Mrs. O’Shea free from contributory negligence, and assessed damages in excess of $
150,000. Riverway appeals only from the finding that there was no contributory
negligence and from the part of the damage award that was intended to compensate Mrs.
O'Shea for her lost future wages.
. . .
The . . . substantial issues in this appeal relate to the computation of lost wages.
Mrs. O'Shea's job as a cook paid her $40 a day, and since the custom was to work 30 days
10. Damages
637
consecutively and then have the next 30 days off, this comes to $7200 a year although, as
we shall see, she never had earned that much in a single year. She testified that when the
accident occurred she had been about to get another cook’s job on a Mississippi towboat
that would have paid her $60 a day ($10,800 a year). She also testified that she had been
intending to work as a boat’s cook until she was 70 -- longer if she was able. An
economist who testified on Mrs. O’Shea's behalf used the foregoing testimony as the
basis for estimating the wages that she lost because of the accident. He first subtracted
federal income tax from yearly wage estimates based on alternative assumptions about
her wage rate (that it would be either $ 40 or $ 60 a day); assumed that this wage would
have grown by between six and eight percent a year; assumed that she would have
worked either to age 65 or to age 70; and then discounted the resulting lost-wage
estimates to present value, using a discount rate of 8.5 percent a year. These calculations,
being based on alternative assumptions concerning starting wage rate, annual wage
increases, and length of employment, yielded a range of values rather than a single value.
The bottom of the range was $50,000. This is the present value, computed at an 8.5
percent discount rate, of Mrs. O'Shea's lost future wages on the assumption that her
starting wage was $40 a day and that it would have grown by six percent a year until she
retired at the age of 65. The top of the range was $114,000, which is the present value
(again discounted at 8.5 percent) of her lost future wages assuming she would have
worked till she was 70 at a wage that would have started at $60 a day and increased by
eight percent a year. The judge awarded a figure -- $86,033 -- near the midpoint of this
range. . . .
There is no doubt that the accident disabled Mrs. O'Shea from working as a cook
on a boat. . . . But Riverway argues that Mrs. O'Shea (who has not worked at all since the
accident, which occurred two years before the trial) could have gotten some sort of job
and that the wages in that job should be deducted from the admittedly higher wages that
she could have earned as a cook on a boat.
The question is not whether Mrs. O'Shea is totally disabled in the sense, relevant
to social security disability cases but not tort cases, that there is no job in the American
economy for which she is medically fit. [ ]. It is whether she can by reasonable diligence
find gainful employment, given the physical condition in which the accident left her. [ ].
Here is a middle-aged woman, very overweight, badly scarred on one arm and one leg,
unsteady on her feet, in constant and serious pain from the accident, with no education
beyond high school and no work skills other than cooking, a job that happens to require
standing for long periods which she is incapable of doing. It seems unlikely that someone
in this condition could find gainful work at the minimum wage. True, the probability is
not zero; and a better procedure, therefore, might have been to subtract from Mrs.
O'Shea's lost future wages as a boat's cook the wages in some other job, discounted (i.e.,
multiplied) by the probability-very low-that she would in fact be able to get another job.
But the district judge cannot be criticized for having failed to use a procedure not
suggested by either party. The question put to him was the dichotomous one, would she
or would she not get another job if she made reasonable efforts to do so? This required
him to decide whether there was a more than 50 percent probability that she would. We
cannot say that the negative answer he gave to that question was clearly erroneous.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT