Cumulative innovation, open source, and distance to frontier

Published date01 December 2020
AuthorLuigi Balletta,Antonio Tesoriere
Date01 December 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12446
J Public Econ Theory. 2020;22:18751920.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet© 2020 Wiley Periodicals LLC
|
1875
Received: 12 June 2019
|
Accepted: 20 April 2020
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12446
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Cumulative innovation, open source, and
distance to frontier
Luigi Balletta
1
|Antonio Tesoriere
2
1
Dipartimento di Economia, Management,
Istituzioni, Università Federico II, Napoli,
Italy
2
S.E.A.S., Università di Palermo, Viale delle
Scienze, Palermo, Italy
Correspondence
Antonio Tesoriere, S.E.A.S. Università di
Palermo, Viale delle Scienze, Ed. 13, 90128
Palermo, Italy.
Email: antonio.tesoriere@unipa.it
Abstract
We develop a multistage game in which firms do
cumulative research and development (R&D) to
complete a lengthy process, and we study whether
firms patent intermediate results or release them in
Open Source. A patent holder obtains a larger reward
in the market, but since in equilibrium it forecloses
R&D, it remains alone to complete the process and so
pays a larger cost than an Open Source firm. We have
Open Source equilibria when R&D is highly com-
plementary, R&D costs are large, and firms are suf-
ficiently different and far from the frontier. We
identify two market failures, in the forms of free
riding and coordination failure, and we discuss public
intervention.
1|INTRODUCTION
In many industries, to obtain a valuable innovation firms have to undertake a lengthy research
and development (R&D) process with many intermediate stages. They pay the operating cost of
the process until it is over, and only then they make a profit by marketing the final result. How
firms grant access to intermediate results determines who may contribute to the innovation and
eventually bring it to the market, and therefore affects both the duration of the process and the
structure of profits downstream. For some processes firms protect their results with proprietary
rights, while for others they leave them open to everyone. In this paper we study firms involved
in a lengthy process, and we provide conditions that in equilibrium firms, markets, and tech-
nology must jointly satisfy for firms to adopt a specific regime of intellectual property rights.
We study processes with some specific characteristics. (i) Firms' R&D activities are com-
plementary. As the number of firms that do R&D increases, so does the probability that one of
them accomplishes a stage. (ii) R&D is sequential and cumulative. By accomplishing a stage a
firm adds a new piece to the technology, but to do so it needs to combine it with the existing
ones. If these are covered by proprietary rights, the firm has to license from the right holder. (iii)
Firms cannot patent infringing innovations, nor can they bargain over research effort. They
bargain over a license, and only after they have done R&D.
We develop a dynamic game of R&D in which firms choose whether to adopt a proprietary
or a nonproprietary regime of licenses. Proprietary licenses work like patent licenses. In ex-
change for a fee the licensor discloses the intermediate result to the licensee and gives this firm
the exclusive right to use the result, but not the right to make copies. Nonproprietary licenses
work like the Open Source General Public License (GPL) in the software industry.
1
The licensee
pays no fee and receives the right both to use the result and to make and distribute copies, but it
agrees to release every copy and improvement under the same terms.
2
In this setup patents create a holdup problem. Since a patent holder can refuse to license
the technology all the times, and complete the process alone, when it bargains over a license it
will ask a fee so large that in the continuation equilibria of the proprietary regime a nonpatent
holder gives up R&D and leaves the gamewe show that this occurs no matter how little is the
patent holder's bargaining power. This in turn generates the tradeoff between final profit and
R&D costs that underlies a firm's choice. The firm anticipates that on the continuation path
with patents the patent holder completes the process by itself and eventually becomes the only
supplier of the good, while on the path with Open Source many firms contribute and then they
share the final market. Since the patent holder faces no competition downstream, it obtains a
final value higher than does an Open Source contributor, but since it forecloses the process to
complementary innovations, it expects to wait longer until completion and hence to pay a
higher operating cost.
In equilibrium firms choose Open Source if and only if (i) the average profit an Open Source
firm obtains over the duration of the process (which is to say the ratio of the profit in the final
market to the expected time to completion) is higher than the operating cost of R&D, and (ii)
this same cost is higher than the average increase in profit that a firm obtains over the incre-
mental duration of the process by choosing patents over Open Source. Firms choose patents if
and only if condition (ii) is violated, and a condition analogous to (i) is satisfied so that the
patent holder breaks even.
The model predicts how the regime of intellectual property rights depends on para-
meters that describe both the R&D process and the downstream market. A first implica-
tion is that firms choose Open Source only when the number of intermediate stages, which
is our measure of distance to frontier, is sufficiently large. For instance, when R&D is not
cumulative they have a dominant strategy in seeking a patent. We can conceive distance to
frontier as the number of institutional steps that a firm has to take to receive the go ahead
from a regulatory agency. More substantively we may conceive it as the number of
cumulative improvements that later movers in an industry has to achieve to catch up
with the current leaders. Our theory suggests that entrants or laggard firms have more
incentives to choose Open Source than established incumbents. It also suggests that firms
aremorelikelytosharetheirintellectualproperty rights when the industry is at its early
stages, at the time they are trying to develop a new technology to replace the existing
1
For a definition of the GNU GPL, see http://www.gnu.org/licenses/gpl3.0.en.html.
2
The way we conceive the proprietary regime applies not just to patents but also to copyrights. Just like patent holders,
copyright holders disclose their innovations through individual license contracts, which often include nondisclosure
clauses that commit the licensee not to make copies (see Cohen & Lemley, 2001; Maurer & Scotchmer, 2006). Ana-
logously, the Open Source regime is also consistent with practices that firms use in industries different from software,
like, the automotive, the biomedical, and the pharmaceutical.
1876
|
BALLETTA AND TESORIERE
alternatives.
3
A second implication is that firms choose Open Source when either the
operating cost or the degree of complementarity of R&D is sufficiently high. Therefore,
given the size of the R&D lab, firms that hire researchers in markets with higher average
earnings have more incentives to choose OpenSource.Sodofirmspursuingprocesses
involving small risk of R&D duplication, for which the probability of discovery is more
likely to increase with the number of labs. Even though we are not concerned with R&D
cooperation, here we note that since saving on duplicative R&D is a main objective of
cooperative R&D agreements, our theory suggests that Open Source licenses and R&D
cooperation should emerge in alternative environments. A final implication is that firms
choose Open Source when the ratio of profits with Open Source to profits with patents is
sufficiently high. This condition depends on the strength of patent protection and on the
cost of imitation in a natural way. It depends also on the effect of entry on joint profit, and
therefore on a set of properties that involve consumers' preferences and firms' costs and
conduct in the final market. Here we remark that this is more likely to happen when the
final good generates network effects, and when firms make most of their profit by selling
goods complementary to the innovation, on which they retain specific competencies and
market power. The model may help us understand the diffusion of the GPL license and of
similar licensing practices both in the software and in other industries. In the paper we
discuss the empirical implications of the model, and go over two examples from the
automotive and the pharmaceutical industry.
We characterize the equilibrium set for all the parameters. We find equilibria in which no
firm does R&D, which occur when the operating cost and the distance to frontier are so large
that a patent holder alone would not afford the process. Associated with these equilibria we find
two types of market failures that block R&D even though firms would afford Open Source. First,
when a firm chooses Open Source, the other has a stronger incentive to free ride and seek a
patent than when the firm is out of the game. When firms break even only with Open Source,
this freeriding motive may preclude equilibria with R&D. Second, when Open Source is ne-
cessary to break even, each firm will do R&D only if it expects the opponent to do so. This
coordination problem supports multiplicity of equilibria, namely, equilibria with Open Source
or equilibria with no R&D. The freerider problem is specific of a region of parameters so small,
and it involves information so detailed to be dealt with that we suggest that a social planner
should not interfere. Instead the coordination problem is pervasive, and we note that, using
only local information, the social planner may address it by subsidizing Open Source R&D in
the same way a multisided platform subsidizes one side to stimulate participation.
1.1 |Related literature
Our paper brings together two strands of the literature on intellectual property rights and
innovation. The recent literature on patents questions that patents are necessary for innovation,
and indeed argues that when innovation is sequential they may slow it down. See Heller and
Eisenberg (1998), Shapiro (2001), and Boldrin and Levine (2008). Bessen and Maskin (2009)
introduce the notion of complementarity we use in this paper, and compare the cases with and
3
Our prediction is broadly consistent with historical evidence. Bessen and Nuvolari (2014) provide examples from the
eighteenth century, like, the Bessemer steel, the steam engineers in the Cornish mining district, and the first two
decades of power weaving in the US textile industry.
BALLETTA AND TESORIERE
|
1877

Get this document and AI-powered insights with a free trial of vLex and Vincent AI

Get Started for Free

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT