Cross‐Hedging Ambiguous Exchange Rate Risk

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/fut.21793
Published date01 February 2017
AuthorKit Pong Wong
Date01 February 2017
Cross-Hedging Ambiguous Exchange
Rate Risk
Kit Pong Wong*
This paper examines the behavior of an exporting firm that sells its output to two foreign coun-
tries, only one of which has futures and options available for its currency. The firm possesses
smooth ambiguity preferences and faces multiple sources of ambiguous exchange rate risk.
We show that the separation theorem fails to hold in that the firm’sproduction and export de-
cisions depend on the firm’s attitude toward ambiguity and on the incident to the underlying
ambiguity.Given that the random spot exchange rates are first-order independent with respect
to each plausible subjective distribution, we derive necessary and sufficient conditions un-
der which the full-hedging theorem applies to the firm’s cross-hedging decisions. When these
conditions are violated, we show that the firm includes options in its optimal hedge position.
This paper as such offers a rationale for the hedging role of options under smooth ambiguity
preferences and cross-hedging of ambiguous exchange rate risk. ©2016 Wiley Periodicals,
Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 37:132–147, 2017
1. INTRODUCTION
According to the 2013 triennial central bank survey of turnover in foreign exchange markets
coordinated by the Bank for International Settlements (BIS), the U.S. dollar remained the
dominant vehicle currency that accounted for 87% of the total daily global turnover in April
2013. The euro and the Japanese yen were the second and third most traded currencies,
respectively. Trading activities increased strongly in currency forwards and options. Trading
volumes of currency forwards reached $680 billion in 2013 from $475 billion in 2010, a
43% increase, while those of currency options increased the most, by more than 60%. The
rise in turnover of currency forwards and options together accounted for almost a quarter of
global foreign exchange turnover growth between 2010 and 2013.
The vast majority of trading of foreign exchange instruments continues to be conducted
over the counter and not traded on organized exchanges, rendering the prevailing use of non-
standardized contractual terms. The minor currencies of the bottom 29 out of 53 countries
included in the BIS triennial survey had an average of 0.134% of the total daily global foreign
exchange turnover in April 2013, which consisted of 0.043% in spot transactions, 0.041%
in outright forwards, 0.042% in foreign exchange swaps, 0.001% in currency swaps, and
0.007% in foreign exchange options. These figures suggest that trading of foreign exchange
instruments of these minor currencies is likely to be thin and illiquid, thereby resulting in
prohibitively high transaction costs. Firms that have positions in these minor currencies
Kit Pong Wong is a Professor of Finance and the Director of the School of Economics and Finance at the
University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong. The author thanks Bob Webb (the editor) and an anonymous referee
for their helpful comments and suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies.
JEL Classification: D21, D81, F31
*Correspondence author,School of Economics and Finance, University of Hong Kong, Pokfulam Road, Hong Kong.
Tel: +852-2859-1044, Fax:+852-2548-1152, e-mail: kpwong@econ.hku.hk
Received August 2015; Accepted April 2016
The Journal of Futures Markets, Vol. 37, No.2, 132–147 (2017)
©2016 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Published online 2 June 2016 in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com).
DOI: 10.1002/fut.21793
Cross-Hedging Ambiguous Exchange Rate Risk 133
are as such induced to look for foreign exchange instruments of a related currency for
hedging purposes. Such an exchange rate risk management technique is referred to as “cross-
hedging.”
The purpose of this paper is to provide theoretical insights into the decision making of
an exporting firm that sells its output to two foreign countries, only one of which has futures
and options available for its currency.To this end, we depart from the extant literature that is
developed within the standard von Neumann–Morgenstern expected utility paradigm (Adam-
M¨
uller, 2000; Broll & Zilcha, 1992; Change & Wong, 2003; Viaene & Zilcha, 1998; Wong,
2013a, 2013b). Takinginto account the possibility that the firm cannot unambiguously assign
a probability distribution that uniquely describes the exchange rate risk, we define uncertainty
in the sense of Knight (1921) to be made up of two components, risk and ambiguity.While risk
aversion is the aversion to a set of outcomes with a known probability distribution, ambiguity
aversion is the additional aversion to being unsure about the probabilities of outcomes.1The
distinction between the known–unknown and the unknown–unknown is relevant, which is
justifiable by ample experiments (Chow & Sarin, 2001; Einhorn & Hogarth, 1986; Sarin
& Weber, 1993) and surveys (Chesson & Viscusi, 2003; Viscusi & Chesson, 1999) that
document convincing evidence that individuals appear to prefer gambles with known rather
than unknown probabilities.
In this paper, we adopt the approach of Klibanoff, Marinacci, and Mukerji (2005)
(hereafter, referred to as the KMM model) to characterize the firm’s preferences by “smooth
ambiguity aversion.” The KMM model has the following recursive structure. First, ambi-
guity is represented by a second-order probability distribution that captures the firm’s un-
certainty about which of the subjective beliefs govern the exchange rate risk. Second, the
firm’s expected utility under ambiguity is measured by taking the second-order expectation
of a concave transformation of the first-order expected utility of profit conditional on each
plausible subjective distribution of the exchange rate risk. This recursive structure creates
a crisp separation between ambiguity and ambiguity aversion, that is, between beliefs and
tastes, which allows the conventional techniques in the decision making under uncertainty
to be applicable in the context of ambiguity (Alary, Gollier, & Treich, 2013; Broll & Wong,
2015; Cherbonnier & Gollier, 2015; Gollier, 2011, 2014; Iwaki & Osaki, 2014; Snow, 2010,
2011; Taboga, 2005; Treich, 2010; Wong, 2015a, 2016a).
As a benchmark, we examine first the case of perfect hedging wherein futures and
options are available for both foreign currencies. In this benchmark case, we show that
the celebrated separation and full-hedging theorems of Danthine (1978), Feder, Just, and
Schmitz (1980), and Holthausen (1979) hold. Specifically, the separation theorem states
that the firm’s production and export decisions are independent of the firm’s preferences
and the underlying exchange rate uncertainty. The full-hedging theorem states that the firm
optimally opts for a double full-hedge via the fairly priced futures for both foreign currencies
so as to completely eliminate its exposure to the exchange rate risk.2As there is no residual
exchange rate risk that is hedgeable, the fairly priced options for both foreign currencies play
no role as a hedging instrument and are not used by the firm.
When the firm can only cross-hedge its exposure to the exchange rate risk, the separa-
tion theorem no longer holds. We show that there is a wedge between the expected marginal
1Dated back to the Ellsberg’s(1961) paradox, ambiguity has been alluded to the violation of the independence axiom,
which is responsible for the decision criterion being linear in the outcome probabilities. See also Dillenberger and
Segal (2015) and Machina (2014).
2The full-hedging theorem is analogous to a well-known result in the insurance literature that a risk-averse individual
fully insures at an actuarially fair price (Mossin, 1968).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT