A Critique of Antitrust Econometrics: Aggregation, the Representative Consumer, and the Broader Concerns of the New Brandeis School

Published date01 March 2022
DOI10.1177/0003603X211067829
Date01 March 2022
https://doi.org/10.1177/0003603X211067829
The Antitrust Bulletin
2022, Vol. 67(1) 69 –99
© The Author(s) 2022
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/0003603X211067829
journals.sagepub.com/home/abx
Article
A Critique of Antitrust Econometrics:
Aggregation, the Representative
Consumer, and the Broader Concerns
of the New Brandeis School
Gabriel A. Lozada*
Abstract
Some economists argue antitrust policy should be based on empirical methods used by the Industrial
Organization subdiscipline of economics, but those methods contain assumptions that noneconomists
should recognize. Those assumptions underlie econometric “identification,” and underlie treating
aggregate demand as if it were generated by a representative consumer (Muellbauer’s “generalized
linear” preferences). We explain aggregation bias in Almost Ideal Demand System models, then show
that data limitations make it even harder to justify economists’ restricting aggregate demands as one
would the demand of one individual. Such problems notwithstanding, the main problem with antitrust
econometrics may be that there is not enough of it. Whether firms maximize profit is understudied
empirically; many may maximize return on assets instead, leading to firms with assets and employees
below their profit-maximizing level. There is insufficient empirical study of this and many other topics
of concern to New Brandeisians.
Keywords
antitrust econometrics, Almost Ideal Demand System (AIDS), myth of shareholder value, financialization
of management, New Brandeis School
In a recent Antitrust magazine article, Carl Shapiro1 makes the case for what he calls the “modern”
approach to the future of antitrust. He stakes out his position in opposition to the “consumer welfare”
camp and the “populist” camp—by the latter he means the New Brandeis School. Under Shapiro’s
“modern” approach, antitrust is reduced to an “effects” analysis based on modern Industrial
Organization. At the apex of this approach is empirical Industrial Organization, where econometrics is
employed to quantify anticompetitive effects (negative welfare effects) and efficiencies (positive
*Department of Economics, The University of Utah, Salt Lake City, UT, USA
Corresponding Author:
Gabriel A. Lozada, Department of Economics, The University of Utah, Salt Lake City, UT 84112, USA.
Email: lozada@economics.utah.edu
1067829ABXXXX10.1177/0003603X211067829The Antitrust BulletinLozada
research-article2022
1. Carl Shapiro, Antitrust: What Went Wrong and How to Fix It, 35/3 antitrust. 33 (2021) at 33–34.
70 The Antitrust Bulletin 67(1)
welfare effects). This exercise usually involves Industrial Organization economists on both sides of the
case. Because of the technical nature of the practice, the economists take center stage. However, many
economists on both sides have been trained to accept certain assumptions, as well as to limit the scope
of their inquiries in important ways.
In Baker and Rubinfeld’s2 survey article, while problems with “identification”3 and “functional
forms”4 are discussed (and will be revisited and explained by us in Section I), no mention is made of
the strong assumptions needed to justify economists’ common practice of applying restrictions from
economic theory to the estimation of aggregate demand systems. Sections II through V of this paper are
devoted to explaining what those assumptions are, including new results along those lines. An addi-
tional assumption underlying most (though not all) econometric approaches is that income but not
wealth determines consumption. That makes little sense outside of a purely theoretical static frame-
work, but abandoning that assumption would require economists to have data not only on household
income but also on household wealth, and the latter is often not available. Once all the assumptions
needed to justify the econometrics are understood, they need not be accepted, raising questions about
how accurate the econometric analyses really are.
Section VI discusses problems using consumer surplus as a measure of consumer welfare, problems
which turn out to be of a similar form to those involved in working with demand systems.
Moving to less mathematical topics, Section VII questions whether firms maximize profit, which
is the assumption underlying almost all neoclassical analysis of firm behavior, and calls for more
econometric analysis of this question. This section reviews the arguments that in the immediate
post–World War II period there were important firms which willingly sacrificed short-term profit to
benefit society as a whole, and that some such firms still exist. If true, that behavior should be taken
into account before allowing such firms to be subject to a hostile takeover. This section also points
out that Wall Street and, accordingly, many large U.S. firms take as firm goals not profit but rather
various financial ratios, especially return on assets. Such a perverted goal can be an immediate
cause of firms wishing to have as few employees and assets as possible. A merger instigated by
managers with such goals can result in merged companies soon having fewer, not more, assets and
employees than the former companies which merged. This decrease in “size” (measured in assets
and employees, rather than in market share or revenues) will falsely be characterized by the pro-
merger parties as “efficiencies” when, in fact, it is probably a welfare-reducing, even profit-reduc-
ing, aspect of the merger. More empirical analysis of firm motives is needed to help enforcement
agencies more carefully distinguish between true merger-specific efficiencies and predatory behav-
ior motivated by short-run financial interests.
The last section of the paper, Section VIII, presses further along the lines of critiquing not what
econometricians have done but what they have not done. These errors of omission may in the final
analysis be a more serious problem than the Industrial Organization econometricians’ errors of com-
mission. The problem with elevating modern Industrial Organization to the center of antitrust policy is
that if important policy goals do not appear in the Industrial Organization literature, they are dismissed
as not relevant to true competition concerns. For example, the effects of practices such as mergers on
workers, small business, the income distribution, and the environment are ignored. Econometrics in
antitrust should be expanded to include analysis from labor economics, environmental economics,
urban and regional economics, and other economics subdisciplines, without which the econometrics
paints only a misleadingly partial picture.
2. Jonathan B. Baker & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, Empirical Methods in Antitrust Litigation: Review and Critique, 1/1 am. Law
Econ. rEv. 386 (1999).
3. Id. at 408.
4. Id. at 413.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT