Crisis and Convergence: How the Combination of a Weak Economy and Mainstream Party Ideological De-Polarization Fuels Anti-System Support

Published date01 June 2021
AuthorZack P. Grant
Date01 June 2021
DOI10.1177/0010414020970222
Subject MatterArticles
https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414020970222
Comparative Political Studies
2021, Vol. 54(7) 1256 –1291
© The Author(s) 2020
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/0010414020970222
journals.sagepub.com/home/cps
Article
Crisis and Convergence:
How the Combination
of a Weak Economy
and Mainstream
Party Ideological De-
Polarization Fuels Anti-
System Support
Zack P. Grant1
Abstract
When do radical parties gain support? Previous studies cite the economy
and mainstream party ideological convergence as important. Responding to
earlier inconsistent findings, I provide evidence for an interactive approach.
Anti-system parties succeed when mainstream parties are simultaneously
presiding over an ailing economy and failing to provide the diversity of
political opinion for the electorate to meaningfully challenge the policies
associated with this malaise, through which dissatisfaction with the status
quo could otherwise be channeled. Two studies support this “crisis and
convergence” model. At the aggregate-level, the anti-system vote is
strongest during times of negative economic growth and widespread
mainstream party ideological de-polarization. At the voter-level, the link
between negative economic evaluations and radical party voting is stronger
during establishment convergence and, vice versa, personal perceptions
of convergence are themselves more closely related to support for these
parties when the macroeconomy is sickly. Mainstream party homogeneity
radicalizes the economic vote and strengthens anti-system challengers.
1University of Oxford, Oxford, UK
Corresponding Author:
Zack P. Grant, St John’s College, University of Oxford, St Giles, Oxford, OX1 3JP, UK.
Email: zack.grant@sjc.ox.ac.uk
970222CPSXXX10.1177/0010414020970222Comparative Political StudiesGrant
research-article2020
Grant 1257
Keywords
anti-system parties, economic voting, polarization, radical politics, party
competition
Introduction
In recent decades the once high institutionalized party systems of the West
have begun to unravel. Relative to their mid-twentieth century predecessors,
contemporary voters are less likely to identify with a single political party
(Dalton & Wattenberg, 2000; Dassonneville et al., 2012; Fieldhouse et al.,
2020, pp. 51–55; Mair, 2013, p. 35), more likely to switch between parties at
successive elections (Bischoff, 2013; Drummond, 2006; Fieldhouse et al.,
2020, pp. 9–14; Mair, 2013, p. 33), and more prone to negative evaluations of
government as a whole (Armingeon & Guthmann, 2014; Catterberg &
Moreno, 2006; OECD, 2017).
Who has benefited from these patterns of distrust and dealignment? The
exact answer varies from country-to-country. From populist mavericks in
Italy, to the nativists of northern Europe, from secessionists in Scotland and
Belgium, to the resurgence of the radical left in southern Europe, from
Eurosceptic challengers in the United Kingdom, to the insurgent Icelandic
Pirate Party. Recent elections have been punctuated by the successes of a
heterogenous mix of “anti-system parties” who stand outside the governing
establishment, and fundamentally challenge the legitimacy of the dominant
norms, values, practices, actors, or boundaries of their political community
(Zulianello, 2018). While the specific ideology or character of these parties
might differ, nearly every advanced Western parliamentary democracy has
witnessed the rise of some form of radical political entrepreneur exploiting
the growing coolness toward the establishment in the past few decades.
What determines the popularity of such parties? Most previous studies have
two notable limitations. First, they tend to only focus on one particular ideo-
logical party family or another. In particular, there is an overwhelming publica-
tion bias toward the so-called “radical right” (Mudde, 2016, p. 2). This does not
reflect the true range of alternatives available for voters looking to express their
disillusionment with the establishment (Abedi, 2002, p. 557). Second, and
more importantly, there is a tendency to focus on demand- and supply-side fac-
tors as separate phenomena (Golder, 2016, pp. 490–491). The former are the
grievances that stimulate desire for radical shifts in policy or modes of repre-
sentation, the latter are the political opportunity structures that determine
whether these latent sentiments actually coalesce around a viable anti-system
party, get co-opted by a pre-existing party, or simply go unrepresented (Eatwell,
2003). Looking at either of these factors in isolation is problematic.
1258 Comparative Political Studies 54(7)
For example, a demand-side grievance that is often linked to the spread of
political radicalism is a weak economy. Recessions are likely to be associated
with many unpleasant experiences for the electorate, most notably mass
unemployment and declining real incomes (Hurd & Rohwedder, 2010;
Singer, 2018). These problems may have the potential to undermine the legit-
imacy of the established constitutional order in the eyes of more output-ori-
ented citizens (Przeworski et al., 1996). Conversely, increasing prosperity
mitigates against defection to untested outsiders by raising the opportunity-
costs of political uncertainty (Brückner & Grüner, 2010, pp. 2–3).
However, it is somewhat unclear why downturns should produce mass
defection to radical anti-system challengers, rather than the simple rotation
between mainstream incumbent and opposition parties described in conven-
tional models of economic voting (Duch & Stevenson, 2008, p. 50; Key, 1966;
Kramer, 1971; Lewis-Beck & Stegmaier, 2000; Whitten & Palmer, 1999). In
severe recessions, parties without a prior history in government or the con-
straining likelihood of actually having to carry out their promises can more
credibly claim non-responsibility for current hardships and be more radical in
proposing resolutions (Hobolt & Tilley, 2016, pp. 972–974). However, it seems
equally plausible that, given the gravity of the situation, risk-averse voters sim-
ply re-elect established parties with substantial governing experience, rather
than leap into the unknown. Research linking radical party fortunes to fluctua-
tions in the macroeconomy has yielded mixed results. While some studies find
a positive association (Arzheimer, 2009; Brückner & Grüner, 2010; Hobolt &
Tilley, 2016; March & Rommerskirchen, 2015; van der Brug et al., 2005),
many others uncover null or even negative findings (Abedi, 2002; Arzheimer
& Carter, 2006; Knigge, 1998; Lubbers et al., 2002; Spies & Franzmann, 2011).
These inconsistencies suggest the influence of supply-side factors, and the
role of the political opportunity structure in denying anti-system candidates
the opportunity to exploit latent anti-establishment sentiment. An obvious
example is mainstream party behavior. Radical parties may find it easier to
mobilize their support when the mainstream parties have become more simi-
lar ideologically. The classic statement comes from Downs (1957). When
established parties of the left and right converge on the median voter, who is
usually assumed to be a centrist, they create a vacuum of unrepresented polit-
ical preferences that can be usurped by parties positioned at the extremes
(Hainsworth, 1992, p. 11). However, the evidence that mainstream party de-
polarization facilitates anti-establishment breakthroughs is, once again,
inconclusive. Some demonstrate a positive association (Abedi, 2002; Carter,
2005; Hino, 2012; Kitschelt & McGann, 1995; Spies & Franzmann, 2011;
Spoon & Klüver, 2019) others do not (Arzheimer & Carter, 2006; Bustikova,
2014; Ignazi, 2003; Lubbers et al., 2002; Norris, 2005).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT