Covert Confiscation: How Governments Differ in Their Strategies of Expropriation

AuthorJane Esberg,Rebecca Perlman
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/00104140221089650
Published date01 January 2023
Date01 January 2023
Subject MatterArticles
https://doi.org/10.1177/00104140221089650
Comparative Political Studies
© The Author(s) 2022
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/00104140221089650
journals.sagepub.com/home/cps
Article
Covert Confiscation:
How Governments
Differ in Their Strategies
of Expropriation
Jane Esberg1 and
Rebecca Perlman2
Abstract
A substantial literature concludes that democratic-type institutions
curb governments’ propensity to expropriate foreign direct investment.
However, little attention has been paid to the strategies of expropriation
regimes employ. We theorize that more politically constrained regimes
will utilize expropriation methods that help them overcome institutional
impediments. Using data on expropriations in developing countries between
1960 and 2014, we show that rather than rely on the most direct and overt
forms of expropriation, constrained regimes tend to use more indirect
and covert methods, such as forced sale or contract renegotiation, tools
which can be harder to identify, easier to justify, and frequently face lower
legislative approval hurdles. Indeed, while more politically constrained
regimes are less likely to overtly expropriate foreign investment than less
constrained regimes, they are nearly as likely to do so covertly, introducing
new questions about the extent to which institutional constraints really
translate into improved protections for foreign investors.
Keywords
foreign direct investment, expropriation, democratic advantage, globalization,
political economy
1Princeton’s Empirical Studies of Conflict Project, Princeton, NJ, USA
2Department of Politics and the School of Public and International Affairs, Princeton
University, Princeton, NJ, USA
Corresponding Author:
Rebecca Perlman, Department of Politics and the School of Public and International Affairs,
445 Robertson Hall, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ 08544-1013 USA.
Email: rebecca.perlman@princeton.edu
1089650
CPSXXX10.1177/00104140221089650Comparative Political StudiesEsberg and Perlman
research-article2022
2023, Vol. 56(1) 3–35
4 Comparative Political Studies 56(1)
1. Introduction
Foreign direct investment (FDI) can provide important benefits to developing
countries, not only spurring productivity and growth but also encouraging the
introduction of new technologies. Yet in order to attract this potentially lucra-
tive form of capital, governments must be able to credibly commit not to
expropriate the property of foreign direct investors. A substantial literature
stemming from the work of Olson (1993) and North and Weingast (1989)
concludes that regimes with more democratic-type institutional constraints
have an inherent advantage when it comes to making such commitments.
Proponents of this view argue that although all regimes may face similar
temptations to expropriate, those governments with increased checks on their
authority through legislative oversight of the executive and public account-
ability should be less likely to act on those temptations (see, e.g., Jensen,
2003, 2006, 2008; Li, 2009; Li & Resnick, 2003). Such theories offer impor-
tant predictions about the rate of expropriation of FDI across various forms
of government, yet there is another element of variation on which these theo-
ries are largely silent: the strategy of expropriation.
While all forced divestment may be undesirable from the perspective of the
original property holder, there are important differences in how involuntary
ownership transfer can be accomplished and the extent to which this is likely
to be curbed by institutional impediments. The most overt forms of expropria-
tion, exemplified by such instances as Venezuela’s issuance of an Expropriation
Decree in 2010 ordering the immediate nationalization of a foreign-owned
glass-container company,1 represent clear and deliberate violations of the
investor’s property rights. By contrast, less outright methods of expropriation,
such as coerced sale or forced contract renegotiation, can similarly transfer
ownership of a private asset to the state without adequate compensation but
may be more difficult for third parties to distinguish from a mutual agreement.
This may allow states to dissemble about the degree to which they are actually
engaging in forced divestment. For example, when Bolivia coerced several oil
companies into selling to the state in 2006, the government made a great show
of claiming that the sale had been voluntary and then used this to argue that no
expropriation had in fact occurred (Quiroga, 2008).
In other words, unlike outright nationalization via executive decree, strat-
egies of expropriation that entail forcing the investor to agree under duress to
sell or otherwise transfer his stake to the state can help governments claim
publicly (albeit insincerely) that the terms of the transfer were fair. This not
only might help reduce the economic consequences of the expropriation and
any concomitant public backlash, but it may also allay the concerns of legis-
lative veto players that the act will lead other investors to pull out en masse,
Esberg and Perlman 5
a consideration that may be particularly important to legislators in so far as
they have investments in foreign-owned companies and other stocks that may
suffer reduced value as a result of domestic expropriations (Jha, 2015). In
fact, as recently as 2012, the Kyrgyzstan legislature blocked an attempt to
engage in outright nationalization of a gold mine while nevertheless later
permitting steps to be taken toward a forced contract renegotiation transfer-
ring a greater portion of the mine to the state (Dzyubenko, 2012). Moreover,
states can even engage in methods of expropriation that bypass the legislature
altogether by pursuing property transfers through extra-legal means, such as
when state-affiliated agents seize the asset in question without official
approval from the central government. Under such extra-legal strategies, leg-
islative constraints on the executive not only become entirely moot but gov-
ernments gain plausible deniability regarding their involvement in the
seizure, helping them avoid any domestic repercussions. Taken together, the
above discussion suggests that executives that face political impediments to
unilateral action may gravitate toward or even prefer methods of expropria-
tion that offer an alternative to the more outright and unambiguous strategy
of nationalization via decree. It also suggests that two of the primary mecha-
nisms often assumed by scholars to play a central role in protecting foreign
investors’ property rights from expropriation—legislative constraints and
audience costs—may be less effective at preventing methods of confiscation
in which government culpability is less clear cut.
Therefore, much as Kono (2006) has suggested that democracies tend to
use less conspicuous methods of trade protections, we theorize that more
constrained governments ought to use methods of forced divestment for
which culpability on the part of the government can be disguised or what we
term “covert” methods of expropriation. Such methods allow politically con-
strained regimes to enjoy the advantages of expropriation, while minimizing
the bite of institutional impediments. By contrast, minimally constrained
governments should tend to rely upon more explicit, outright methods of
property transfer or what we term “overt” forms of expropriation. Overt
expropriation, as exemplified by the previously mentioned Venezuelan case,
is typically accomplished via an official act of the legislature (where one
exists) or via executive writ. This is desirable for leaders with fewer checks
on their authority because it provides an immediate and sizable benefit that
accrues directly to the state without requiring any sort of extended show of
negotiation with the aggrieved party, as can be required in the case of forced
sales or contract renegotiations. At the same time, this strategy is also the
most obviously expropriatory and, as we will demonstrate, the most difficult
to achieve in the face of institutional impediments, which should make it less
viable for more politically constrained regimes.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT