Costly Self‐Insurance of Rights Offerings

AuthorRajdeep Singh,Eng‐Joo Tan,Truong X. Duong
Published date01 November 2015
Date01 November 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jbfa.12168
Journal of Business Finance & Accounting
Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 42(9) & (10), 1251–1281, November/December 2015, 0306-686X
doi: 10.1111/jbfa.12168
Costly Self-Insurance of Rights Offerings
TRUONG X. DUONG,RAJDEEP SINGH AND ENG-JOO TAN
Abstract: We study how the underwriting decision of an equity rights offering is affected by
the risk of offering failure. Firms can reduce failure risk by getting underwriting or by self-
insuring through subscription price discounts and subscription precommitments. Self-insurance
is generally regarded to be relatively costless, but we provide evidence from Singapore that
is consistent with the existence of implicit costs. In particular, the existence of self-insurance
costs implies that firms with better projects will have larger discounts and that firms with higher
ownership concentration will have more precommitments. Hence, our results support costly
self-insurance against issue failure as a factor in explaining the rights issue paradox.
Keywords: rights, paradox, failure, seasoned equity offerings
1. INTRODUCTION
Equity rights offers have presented a challenge to financial economists over the
past three decades. Smith (1977) describes a rights issue paradox, where corporate
managers prefer firm commitment offerings to rights offerings even though the
former are more costly, with direct flotation costs estimated to be 6.17% and 2.45%
of the proceeds, respectively.1Furthermore, Eckbo (2008) notes that the percentage
of rights issues among US seasoned equity offerings (SEOs henceforth) shrunk from
50% during 1935–1955 to 2% during 1980–2008; given that $730 billion were raised
during the latter period via firm commitment offerings, the direct cost differential
implies $27 billion have potentially been incurred due to suboptimal choices by firms.
In addition, a multitude of studies document an increasing reliance on underwriter-
intermediated SEOs in other parts of the world (e.g., in Canada (Ursel and Trepanier,
The first author is at the College of Business, Iowa State University. The second author is at the Carlson
School of Management, University of Minnesota. The third author is at the Lee Kong Chian School
of Business, Singapore Management University. The authors would like to thank Ren´
ee Adams, Sugato
Bhattacharyya, Clifford Holderness, Jennifer Huang, Stacey Jacobsen, Roger Loh, Ronald Masulis, Garry
Twite, Kazuo Yamada, as well as the participants of the 2010 Singapore Management University Finance
Summer Camp, 2011 Asian Finance Association Meeting, 2011 Financial Management Association Annual
Meeting, and 2013 European Financial Management Association Annual Conference for their helpful
comments. The authors are especially grateful to the Associate Editor, Norman Strong, and an anonymous
referee for their invaluable suggestions. Any remaining errors are, of course, the responsibility of the
authors. (Paper received December 2014, revised version accepted October 2015).
Address for correspondence: Truong X. Duong, College of Business, Iowa State University, 1200 Gerdin
Business Building, Ames, IA 50011, USA.
e-mail: tduong@iastate.edu
1 The most common equity flotation mechanisms are the firm commitment offering and the standby rights
offering, both of which are underwritten, and the uninsured rights offering, which is not underwritten.
C
2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 1251
1252 DUONG, SINGH AND TAN
2001), Hong Kong (Wu et al., 2005), Japan (Eckbo et al., 2007), France (Gajewski and
Ginglinger, 2002), and Norway (Bøhren et al., 1997)).
Resolution of the paradox, unfortunately, remains elusive as it is challenging to
show that omitted costs (benefits) associated with non-underwritten (underwritten)
offers are sufficient to explain the direct cost differential, because to do so requires one
to estimate the economic significance of counterfactual elements. Moreover, countries
such as the United States for which the paradox is severe make undesirable test beds
because of their poor sample sizes, necessitating research on other countries in seeking
resolution. Studying the paradox in a setting where no paradox is observed is not, in
itself, inappropriate as long as there are common drivers of equity flotation mechanism
choice.
When an equity offering fails, the inability to raise the requisite proceeds imposes
a cost due to project opportunity loss or delay, which we refer to as failure cost
henceforth. For a firm commitment offering, the expected failure cost is trivial
because the offering is underwritten. For a non-underwritten rights offering, conven-
tional academic wisdom (e.g., Smith (1977)) suggests that self-insurance through a
sufficiently low subscription price is effectively costless, which implies an expected
failure cost that is close to zero. Yet, Bacon (1972), among others, notes corporate
managers appear averse to setting low subscription prices. Prior studies provide
reasonable bases for this puzzling behavior: Heinkel and Schwartz (1986) theorize
that undervalued firms set subscription prices at higher levels to signal their higher
quality while Holderness and Pontiff (2013) document that deeply discounted rights
offerings effect a substantial wealth transfer from non-participating to participating
shareholders.
Is self-insurance really costless? In this paper, we develop and test implications of
costly self-insurance. All else equal, corporate managers should choose equity flotation
methods with the lowest expected cost, which comprises not only direct costs but
also indirect costs such as failure costs and self-insurance costs (i.e., costs incurred
due to actions taken to avert offering failure). We argue that even though lowering
the subscription price of an offering reduces the failure cost, if subscription price
discounting is costly, managers are effectively trading off the cost of discounting
against the cost of failure.
In addition to subscription price discounting, an issuer can reduce expected failure
cost by obtaining precommitments from its shareholders to subscribe to its offering;
however, this form of self-insurance too is possibly not costless, as corporate managers
have to expend time and effort to procure sufficient subscription precommitments to
ensure the success of the offering. Thus, a firm that undertakes an uninsured rights
offering with subscription precommitments is trading off the cost of failure against
the opportunity cost of managerial time spent soliciting precommitments, where the
latter cost is likely a function of the firm’s ownership structure. Since failure cost is
relevant to the self-insurance decision only in the face of costly self-insurance mech-
anisms, we refer to our hypotheses collectively as the costly self-insurance hypothesis
(CSIH).
Although both non-underwritten and underwritten rights offerings are becoming
increasingly infrequent in the US, the paradox is really due to the dearth of
non-underwritten rights offerings, since underwritten rights and firm commitment
offerings have similar direct costs (see, e.g, Smith (1977)). Furthermore, as the
underwritten rights offering captures the salient features of the firm commitment
C
2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT