Corporate Social Performance, Competitive Advantage, Earnings Persistence and Firm Value

Published date01 January 2016
Date01 January 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jbfa.12182
AuthorXiaojuan Yan,Julie Whittaker,Alan Gregory
Journal of Business Finance & Accounting
Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 43(1) & (2), 3–30, January/February 2016, 0306-686X
doi: 10.1111/jbfa.12182
Corporate Social Performance,
Competitive Advantage, Earnings
Persistence and Firm Value
ALAN GREGORY,JULIE WHITTAKER AND XIAOJUAN YAN
Abstract: In this paper, using a generalised valuation framework inspired by Ohlson, we show
that corporate social performance (CSP) is value relevant and that, in particular, it appears
to be associated with a higher coefficient on earnings. This could be attributable to either a
lower cost of equity for these firms, or greater earnings persistence. We show that, once industry
membership is controlled for, any cost of capital effect is minimal. Regression tests based on
realised earnings confirm that the valuation effect is attributable mainly to greater earnings
persistence in firms with higher levels of CSP. These outcomes are consistent with higher CSP
conferring a competitive advantage on firms.
Keywords: corporate social responsibility, corporate social performance, competitive advantage,
value relevance, earnings persistence
1. INTRODUCTION
Can a firm’s corporate social performance (CSP) endow it with a competitive advan-
tage and, thereby, improve its earnings? Friedman (1962, 1970) famously expressed
disquiet about agency losses from socially responsible actions but, notably, he was
not opposed to corporate social responsibility if it enhanced firm value. His views
motivated a large body of empirical work investigating if there is a business case for
corporate social responsibility (CSR). Renneboog et al. (2008) review this literature
and conclude that whether or not CSR is priced in capital markets is an open question.
However, recent studies that focus on firm value, as we do here, find evidence that
CSP does impact positively on firm value (Galema et al., 2008; Guenster et al., 2011;
Jo and Harjoto, 2011; Kim and Statman, 2012; and Gregory and Whittaker, 2013).
Nonetheless, even if firms with a high corporate social performance (CSP) are found
to have a higher stock value than firms with low CSP, this still leaves open the
The first and second authors are from the University of Exeter. The third author (Xiaojuan Yan) was a
Phd student at the University at the time the paper was commenced. The authors are grateful to session
participants at the FMA Conference in Porto, to seminar participants at Glasgow University, St Andrew’s
University and Exeter University, Rajesh Tharyan and Grzegorz Trojanowskiand to an anonymous referee.
They are particularly grateful to Andy Stark (the JBFA Editor for this paper) for his helpful and constructive
suggestions during revisions to this paper. The usual disclaimers with regard to errors and omissions apply.
(Paper received December 2014, revised version accepted January 2016).
Address for correspondence: Alan Gregory, University of Exeter,Exeter, Devon EX4 4PU, United Kingdom
e-mail: a.gregory@ex.ac.uk
C
2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 3
4GREGORY, WHITTAKERAND YAN
possibility that this is a consequence of greater investor demand for the stocks of
‘good’ companies (Mackey et al., 2007) while, as suggested by El Ghoul et al. (2011),
companies with an inferior CSP may have a smaller investor base. The contribution
of this paper is not only simply to show that CSP is value enhancing, but also to show
that the reason CSP is value relevant is that CSP appears to be associated with greater
earnings persistence. The implication is that the relationship between CSP and firm
value is driven by an underlying economic effect that is consistent with firms that have
higher levels of CSP having a competitive advantage over rival firms.
Our investigative approach is consistent with that of Agarwal et al. (2011) and
Gregory and Whittaker (2013). Both papers argue that firm value, rather than realised
returns, is the more appropriate metric when assessing the financial implications of
the objects of their investigations. The reason is straightforward, in that the analysis
of realised returns will tell us nothing if markets are efficient. As Agarwal et al.
(2011) point out, ‘In efficient markets, there should be no relationship between
quality of management and subsequent stock returns as implications of management
quality will already be impounded in the stock price. This is irrespective of whether
it has a positive, negative or no impact on firm operating performance’. Gregory and
Whittaker (2013) make a similar point with regard to CSP, emphasising that if CSP is
associated with a lower cost of capital (as suggested by Sharfman and Fernando, 2008
and El Ghoul et al., 2011), then we would expect to observe high CSP firms having
lower returns on average than low CSP firms.
In this study we use a more sophisticated value-based model than that employed in
Gregory and Whittaker (2013) and apply it not only to retest the impact of CSP on firm
value but, after finding that firms with a high CSP do have a higher value, also explore
whether this is because earnings themselves are more persistent and whether they
have a lower risk-adjusted cost of capital resulting in a higher capitalisation of future
earnings. In this respect, our approach is similar to that adopted in Agarwal et al.
(2011), although our modelling of valuation and earnings effects is subtly different. In
common with Agarwal et al. (2011), we also investigate whether risk-adjusted costs of
capital differ between firms with good and poor CSP performance with respect to our
chosen metrics. In contrast to the findings of Sharfman and Fernando (2008) and El
Ghoul et al. (2011), we find that, once industry membership is controlled for, any cost
of capital difference between high and low CSP firms is minimal. However, we find
that CSP positively predicts future earnings and therefore high CSP would appear to
be associated with higher future abnormal earnings. Therefore we conclude that CSR
engagement can endow firms with a competitive advantage by raising future earnings.
2. THEORY AND HYPOTHESES
The ability of a firm to gain a competitive advantage is normally considered from the
resource-based view (RBV), which assumes firm heterogeneity. Firms with resources
and capabilities that are valuable and rare attain economic rents and, when these are
difficult to imitate or substitute, the competitive advantage is sustainable over the long
term (Barney, 1991). However, Oliver (1997) argues that an institutional perspective is
also relevant for understanding competitive advantage, because conforming to social
expectations is pertinent for organisational success and survival (Scott, 1987; Carroll
and Hannan, 1989; and Oliver, 1991). An early response to Friedman’s concern with
agency losses associated with CSR is provided by Narver (1971), who stresses the
C
2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT