Corporate Power and Expansive U.S. Military Policy

AuthorMason Gaffney
Date01 March 2018
Published date01 March 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ajes.12222
Corporate Power and Expansive
U.S. Military Policy
By MASON GAFFNEY*
ABSTRACT. Military defense is generally treated in economics texts as a
“public good” because the benefits are presumed to be shared by all
citizens. However, defense spending by the United States cannot
legitimately be classified as a public good, since the primary purpose of
those expenditures has been to project power in support of private
business interests. Throughout the course of the 20
th
century, U.S.
military spending has been largely devoted to protecting the overseas
assets of multinational corporations that are based in the United States
or allied nations. Companies extracting oil, mineral ores, timber, and
other raw materials are the primary beneficiaries. The U.S. military
provides its services by supporting compliant political leaders in
developing countries and by punishing or deposing regimes that
threaten the interests of U.S.-based corporations. The companies
involved in this process generally have invested only a small amount of
their own capital. Instead, the value of their overseas assets largely
derives from the appreciation of oil and other raw materials in situ.
Companies bought resource-rich lands cheaply, as early as the 1930s or
1940s, and then waited for decades to develop them. In order to make
a profit on this long-range strategy, they formed cartels to limit global
supply and relied on the U.S. military to help them maintain secure title
over a period of decades. Those operations have required suppressing
democratic impulses in dozens of nations. The global “sprawl” of
extractive companies has been the catalyst of U.S. foreign policyfor the
past century. The U.S. Department of Defense provides a giant subsidy
to companies operating overseas, and the cost is borne by the
taxpayers of the United States, not by the corporate beneficiaries.
*Professor of economics emeritus at University of California, Riverside. Email:
m.gaffney@dslextreme.com. Author of After the Crash: Designing a Depression-Free
Economy (2009) and The Corruption of Economics (1994). The latter examines how
economics was historically distracted from its potential to create models of an econ-
omy based on both efficiency and equity.
American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 77, No. 2 (March, 2018).
DOI: 10.1111/ajes.12222
V
C2018 American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Inc.
Defining military spending as a “public good” has been a mistake with
global ramifications, leading to patriotic support for imperialist
behavior.
Introduction
Corporations are heavily involved in the military programs of the
United States.
1
On the one hand, they build weapons systems for the
Pentagon under contract, often with large cost overruns. On the other
hand, all American corporations with overseas investments benefit
from U.S. military spending. The net effect is that business ties with the
military have increased the power of corporations, distorted the politi-
cal system in the United States in favor of elite interests, encouraged
waste of productive potential, and led to the United States functioning
as the world’s police force. That last effect is part of an expansionist for-
eign policy that has embroiled the United States in military action
almost every year of the 20
th
and 21
st
centuries (Grimmett 2010: 7–30).
On the procurement side, consider only the latest fiasco. The F-35 jet
program, built by Lockheed-Martin, is currently scheduled, after seven
years of delay, to cost $406.5 billion for procurement and over $1 trillion
in lifetime operating and maintenance costs (Capaccio 2017). The project
has been the object of ongoing criticism from the U.S. Congress. The F-35
is less combat-ready than its predecessors, but despite its litany of techni-
cal problems, the Pentagon has deemed it “too big to fail” (Hughes 2017).
This is an exaggerated case of corporate welfare—a situation in which a
corporation is able continually to draw upon public revenues for an infe-
rior product, all because that corporation has amassed so much political
power. Bender, Rosen, and Gould (2014) show how Lockheed Martin is
able to influence the political system by the use of strategically located
subcontractors dispersed around the United States and the world:
One reason why the project has become such a boondoggle is that many
states and countries are significantly invested in the plane, relying on its
production for income and jobs. Every U.S. state but Alaska, Hawaii,
Nebraska, and Wyoming has economic ties to the F-35, with 18 states
counting on the project for $100 million or more in economic activity,
according to primary contractor Lockheed Martin. All told, the project is
The American Journal of Economics and Sociology332
supposedly responsible for 32,500 jobs in the U.S. Globally, another nine
countries have major ties to the F-35.
This is how corporations function in the world of defense contracts.
They create “white elephants” that the government is forced to buy to
avoid angering the constituency of key members of Congress.
On the other side of the ledger are the more than $5 trillion in assets
held by U.S. corporations in foreign countries (US CIA 2016). The U.S.
military devotes a large portion of its resources to protecting those
foreign investments, although it defines those assets as “the interests of
the United States.” Few people who use that language stop to think that
those interests are mostly private, not public. Why should someone
who invests in a company with oilfields in Angola, Kazakhstan, or
Sudan receive the protection of U.S. military forces without any charge?
Why should American taxpayers pay this cost? Why should young
Americans be sent to fight to protect those investments? Why should
the United States provoke other countries into becoming “endless ene-
mies” to protect private investments (Kwitny 1984)? There is no reason
the price of oil could not reflect the true cost of obtaining it. Alterna-
tively, some international body might collect the oil rents so there
would be less value worth fighting over. In fact, American taxpayers
spent about $50 billion a year in the 1990s to project American power
into the Persian Gulf. If that cost had been factored into the price of oil,
the true net cost of oil from that region would have reached $100 per
barrel by the mid-1990s(Lovins and Lovins 1995).
The question that I seek to answer in this article is how corporations
have managed to cloak themselves with patriotism when their assets
are at risk in other countries and yet refuse to share the benefits of their
activities with the governments that pay for these protection services.
This does not mean that the U.S. military spends no money on
legitimate security interests. But in a world where corporate interests
have become so closely tied to American foreign policy, it is difficult to
know precisely where to drawthe line.
The Fig Leaf: Defense as a Public Good
The use of military spending in the United States to defend private
interests has received surprisingly little attention over the years.
Corporate Power & U.S. Military Policy 333

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT