CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND CAPITAL STRUCTURE DYNAMICS: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY

AuthorWei Wang,Tarun Mukherjee,Li‐Kai (Connie) Liao
Date01 June 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jfir.12057
Published date01 June 2015
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE AND CAPITAL STRUCTURE DYNAMICS:
AN EMPIRICAL STUDY
Li-Kai (Connie) Liao
Tunghai University
Tarun Mukherjee
University of New Orleans
Wei Wang
Cleveland State University
Abstract
Consistent with theoretical predictions, we nd that both a higher level of nancial
leverage and a faster speed of adjustment of leverage toward the shareholdersdesired
level are associated with better corporate governance quality as dened by a more
independent board featuring CEOchairman separation and greater presence of outside
directors, coupled with larger institutional shareholding. In contrast, managerial
incentive compensation on average discourages use of debt or adjustments toward the
shareholdersdesired level, consistent with its entrenchment effect. The effect of
corporate governance on leverage adjustments is most pronounced when initial leverage
is between the managers desired level and the shareholdersdesired level where the
interests of managers and shareholders conict.
JEL Classification: G30, G32, G34
I. Introduction
According to the static trade-off theory, a rm maximizes the wealth of its shareholders
when its capital structure reaches the optimal level via a trade-off of tax benets against
nancial distresscosts of debt. Consequently, any deviation from optimalleverage should
be removed quickly. However, empirical studies show incomplete leverage rebalancing
(e.g., Flanneryand Rangan 2006; Lemmon, Roberts, andZender 2008), often attributed by
researchers (e.g., Fischer, Heinkel, and Zechner 1989; Strebulaev 2007) to renancing
costs.
1
In a recent paper calling attentionto the role of agency conicts in capital structure
decisions, Morellec, Nikolov, and Sch
urhoff (2012) offer another explanation for why
capital structure speedof adjustment (SOA) is slower than what the static trade-off theory
We are immensely grateful to Mark Flannery, the associate editor, and
Ozde
Oztekin, the referee, for giving
us countless helpful suggestions that have substantially improved the papers quality and contribution. We also
thank the editors for guiding us through the entire process. The usual caveat applies.
1
Other factors that could lead to partial adjustment of capital structure include equity mispricing (e.g., Warr
et al. 2012), cash-ow realization (Faulkender et al. 2012), institutional and macroeconomic factors (
Oztekin and
Flannery 2012;
Oztekin forthcoming), and so on.
The Journal of Financial Research Vol. XXXVIII, No. 2 Pages 169191 Summer 2015
169
© 2015 The Authors. The Journal of Financial Research published by Wiley Periodicals, Inc. on behalf of The Southern Finance Association and
the Southwestern Finance Association
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial License, which permits use, distribution and
reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited and is not used for commercial purposes.
RAWLS COLLEGE OF BUSINESS, TEXAS TECH UNIVERSITY
PUBLISHED FOR THE SOUTHERN AND SOUTHWESTERN
FINANCE ASSOCIATIONS BY WILEY-BLACKWELL PUBLISHING
would predict. Internalizing managersprivate benets in an augmented trade-off model
where rms face taxation,liquidation costs, and renancing costs,Morellec, Nikolov, and
Sch
urhoff demonstrate thatto produce the empirical SOA, one must introducereasonable
agency costs. When makingnancing decisions, self-interested managers tradeoff the tax
benets of debt againstthe total costs of debt, including not only costsof nancial distress
but also those due to the disciplining effect of debt, that is, the loss of free cash ow at
managersdiscretion for potential private benets (Jensen 1986). As a result, managers
issue less debt and restructure less frequently than is optimal for shareholders. In other
words, managers on average would have a leverage target that is lower than the
shareholdersdesired level and employ a slower SOA. Based on their model, Morellec,
Nikolov, and Sch
urhoff further argue that an effective corporate governance system
advances shareholdersinterest by persuading managers to use more debt as well as to
make more timely capital structure rebalancing. Overall, they show that agency conicts
have a rst-order effect on capital structure decisions.
In this article we empirically test the intriguing implications of the Morellec,
Nikolov, and Sch
urhoff (2012) model: the greater the severity of agency conicts, the
lower is the managers desired leverage level, and the slower is the SOA toward the
shareholdersdesired level. We relate a rms capital structure decisions to its agency
costs that in turn depend on the governance system within which the rm operates. To
measure the strength of the rms corporate governance, we focus on the composition of
the board of directors it chooses, the executive compensation it pays, and the institutional
ownership it attracts. Directors and institutional investors monitor and discipline the
managers to contain agency conicts, and we expect they would encourage the use of
debt and facilitate capital structure rebalancing. As board independence is viewed as
crucial for effective monitoring, we characterize a strong board of directors by the
separation between CEO and board chairman (e.g., Fama and Jensen 1983), and a high
proportion of outside directors (e.g., Weisbach 1988). The higher the institutional
holding, all else the same, the more effectively institutional owners monitor the managers
(e.g., Shleifer and Vishny 1986). Equity-based compensation packages aim at
incentivizing the managers but have the unintended consequence of causing managerial
entrenchment (Claessens et al. 2002) in the form of, among others, lower than optimal
leverage (Berger, Ofek, and Yermack 1997). Morellec, Nikolov, and Sch
urhoff
document that on average a greater managerial delta, that is, sensitivity of managerial
compensation to stock price changes, is associated with greater agency costs as far as
capital structure decisions are concerned.
2
Therefore, we expect that, holding all else
equal, a high managerial delta discourages the manager from using debt and thereby
reduces his incentive to adjust the rms capital structure toward the shareholders
desired level. We also create an aggregate governance quality factor by applying
principal component analysis (PCA) on the above four governance variables, and we
expect this proxy of strong governance to be positively associated with SOA.
2
Morrelec, Nikolov, and Sch
urhoff (2012) document a U-shaped but on average positive relation between the
private benet of control and managerial delta, consistent with the incentive versus entrenchment literature. They
suggest that, overall, the protection provided by managerial ownership outweighs the benets for the manager from
the increased use of debt.
170 The Journal of Financial Research

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT