Copyrights, criminal sanctions and economic rents: applying the rent seeking model to the criminal law formulation process.
Jurisdiction | United States |
Author | Saperstein, Lanier |
Date | 22 June 1997 |
I. Introduction
Few, if any, public choice theorists(1) have applied the rent seeking
model(2) to the criminal law formulation process.(3) This is particularly
odd given that rent seeking is such a prevalent model in examining
the formulation of civil legislation.(4) On first inspection, public choice
theorists may posit that the benefits of criminal law are public goods.(5)
For example, streets which are free from criminal activity offer
benefits that are nonexcludable and nonrivalrous. Accordingly, interest
groups have little incentive to organize on the ground that the
benefits of their collective action would be available to the public at large,
yet they would have to bear the entire cost of organization. This may
well be true for some aspects of criminal law, in particular policies of
general deterrence. On closer inspection, however, there are areas of
criminal law which enable organized interests to use the mechanism
of government to create or protect economic rents. These areas lend
themselves to rent seeking analysis.
In order to clarify the argument, this Comment will examine the
changing nature of copyright law. Copyright law is making increased
use of criminal sanctions to punish transgressions.(6) Prior to 1976, for
example, the maximum criminal sanction for the willful infringement
of a copyright by an individual constituted a misdemeanor penalty of
$1,000 and one year in prison.(7) After 1992, by contrast, the maximum
criminal sanction for the willful infringement of a copyright by an
individual constituted a felony penalty of $250,000 and five years in
prison (for first time offenders) and ten years (for second time
offenders).(8) Thus, there has been a clear and dramatic shift toward
stiffer and more stringent criminal penalties for copyright infringement.
This Comment posits that the traditional public choice model of
rent seeking can explain the increase in criminal sanctions for
copyright infringements. As the value of intellectual property rights has
increased with the emergence of new technology, particularly in the
area of computer software, the incentives for interests to expend
resources in order to gain monopolies over these products have also
increased.(9) This Comment argues that Congress' decision to increase
criminal penalties was driven by interest groups seeking copyrights
protected by criminal sanctions as a means of restricting entry into an
increasingly profitable market. Indeed, given the nature of
intellectual property, criminal sanctions are the most effective means of
restricting competition and realizing economic rents. Thus, this
Comment extends the methodology of public choice from the civil to
the criminal law formulation process. To public choice theorists such
an argument may not seem particularly controversial. To legal
scholars, however, such thinking may be quite revolutionary.
The fundamental purpose of the Comment is thus to
demonstrate that the criminal law formulation process does not occur in a
political vacuum; namely, it is not a frictionless process void of interest
group activity. Given that quotas, tariffs and regulations are coveted
by economic interests,(10) it would seem reasonable to suggest that
certain criminal sanctions are also coveted by economic interests. The
secondary purpose of the Comment is to suggest that copyright
protection may be inappropriate for certain works. Specifically,
government-conferred copyrights enable the holder to realize economic
rents, and these rents offer an incentive for interest groups to expend
resources in order to gain these copyrights. This process of rent
seeking means that there are greater costs associated with the current
system of copyrights than the present literature suggests. Indeed, when
these costs are factored into the equation, the benefits of copyright
protection may not, on balance, outweigh the costs. It is important to
emphasize, however, that the Comment's analysis is predominately
positive (i.e., non-normative) and specific policy choices are beyond
its scope.
In order to develop the above thesis, section II explores the
increasingly criminal nature of copyright law and the legislative history
behind the three most recent amendments to the Copyright Act.
Section III explains the rent seeking model in some detail. Section IV
gives a brief overview of the economics of intellectual property.
Section V discusses the need for criminal sanctions as a means of
deterring entry into a lucrative market for copyrighted material. This
section applies the rent seeking model to the legislative history of the
Copyright Act. Section V does not claim to prove a causal connection
between interest group demands and the resulting law, but rather a
conceptual correlation.(11) Some readers may view this section as pure
assertion, and indeed, there is considerable scope for future research.
This Comment, far from being the final word on the phenomenon of
rent seeking in the area of copyright law, is meant to suggest the need
for empirical research and further study. Finally, Section VI
concludes.
II. The Increase in Criminal Sanctions for Copyright Infringement
For more than one hundred years, the federal government did
not impose criminal penalties for copyright infringement.(12) In 1897,
Congress amended the federal copyright law and, for the first time,
promulgated criminal sanctions for those who infringed protected
copyrights.(13) The actions giving rise to criminal sanctions, however,
were limited to unlawful performances and representations of
copyrighted dramatic and musical compositions. The newly amended
Copyright Act provided, "[i]f the unlawful performance and
representation be willful and for profit, such person or persons shall be guilty
of a misdemeanor and upon conviction may be imprisoned for a
period not exceeding one year."(14) Other forms of copyright
infringement such as the unauthorized reproduction or distribution of a
copyrighted work continued to be resolved through civil litigation.(15)
The first attempt to broaden criminal sanctions for copyright
infringement occurred during the general copyright revision of 1909.(16)
The process that led to the Copyright Act of 1909(17) was driven by
industry representatives with a vested interest in copyright law.(18) In
order to revise the copyright laws, the Librarian of Congress convened a
series of conferences.(19) Invited to the conferences were
representatives of industries protected by copyright legislation.(20) The draft
bill generated out of these conferences, however, encountered opposition
from other interest groups not represented at the conferences.(21) This
conflict was resolved by subsequent negotiations between the various
groups, and it was this interest group compromise that became the
1909 statute.(22) The 1909 Copyright Act applied criminal
infringement provisions to all types of copyrighted works except sound
recordings.(23) The Act provided misdemeanor penalties of up to one
year in jail or a fine between $100 and $1,000, or both, for "any
person who willfully and for profit" infringed upon a protected
copyright.(24)
By 1971, there was a substantial increase in unauthorized record
and tape duplication. For example, the House of Representatives
Judiciary Committee estimated that the annual volume of unauthorized
record and tape duplication exceeded $100 million.(25) The
Committee traced the problem to the exclusion of sound recordings from
criminal copyright infringement provisions.(26) As Mary Jane Saunders
notes, "[i]n response to demands from the sound recording industry,
Congress extended general federal copyright protection to sound
recordings with the Sound Recording Act of 1971."(27) Criminal
sanctions, for the first time, were available against those who willfully and
for profit infringement upon the copyright of protected sound
recordings.
Apart from the Sound Recording Act of 1971, which represented
an incremental adjustment, criminal copyright law remained largely
unchanged from the original Copyright Act of 1909.(28) Indeed, in
1976 the House of Representatives Judiciary Committee noted that
"[t]he present copyright law ... is basically the same as the act of
1909."(29) There had been, however, dramatic changes in technology.
Since 1909, a wide range of new techniques for capturing and
communicating printed matter, visual images and recorded sounds had
emerged.(30) These technical advances generated new industries and
new methods for the reproduction and dissemination of copyrighted
works.(31)
Despite the rapid change in technology and the growth of new
information-based industries, Congress did not provide a comprehensive
revision of the copyright law until 1976.(32) The legislative history
behind the Copyright law until of 1976(33) is long and complex.(34) There
were more than thirty studies, three reports issued by the Register of
Copyrights, four panel discussions issued as committee prints, six
series of subcommittee hearings, eighteen committee reports, and the
introduction of at least nineteen general revision bills over a period of
more than twenty years.(35)
Most commentators agree that the final version of the Act was the
result of interest group negotiations and compromise through
congressional institutional structures.(36) As Professor Litman observed,
"[m]ost of the statutory language was not drafted by members of
Congress or their staffs at all."(37) Rather, the language evolved through a
process of negotiation among authors, publishers, and other parties
with economic interests in the property rights that the statute
created.(38) Indeed, by the time the House and Senate subcommittees
began holding hearings on copyright revision legislation, the
participants in the pre-hearing negotiations had reached agreement
on the bill's basic structure.(39) "Members of Congress openly
acknowledged their limited substantive expertise and their largely supervisory
role in the drafting process."(40)
The...
To continue reading
Request your trialCOPYRIGHT GALE, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.