Convenience Yields in Electricity Prices: Evidence from the Natural Gas Market

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/fut.21807
AuthorNikolaos Paratsiokas,Nikolaos Milonas
Date01 May 2017
Published date01 May 2017
Convenience Yields in Electricity Prices:
Evidence from the Natural Gas Market
Nikolaos Milonas* and Nikolaos Paratsiokas
This study develops a model in which changes in the electricity basis are directly related to
changes in the fuels storage level and the fuels convenience yield. The model is tested with
data from the US electricity and natural gas markets during the period 20042014. Empirical
results show a negative relationship between the electricity basis and the fuels convenience
yield giving support to the argument that non-storable commodities embody convenience
yields. © 2016 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 37:522538, 2017
1. INTRODUCTION
This paper examines the existence of convenience yields in electricity prices. Because
electricity is non-storable, it is largely assumed that convenience yields are absent from
electricity prices. The approach followed here focuses on the convenience yield embodied in
the prices of fuels used to produce electricity. Upon a sudden shortage of the fuel, its spot
price will increase relatively to the futures price giving rise to convenience yields. The idea
rests upon the fact that electricity is the output of burning a given fuel through a production
transformation process. The transformation to electricity will not occur unless the value of
fuel (including the convenience yield) is also transferred to the electricity output. Therefore,
in a free and competitive market, the increase in the fuel cost will give rise to an increase in
the electricity price. The latter will indirectly encompass the convenience yield of the
respective fuel.
Studying convenience yield is important to researchers and traders because it is a basic
determinant of the theory of storage and the pricing of futures contracts. Developed in the
earlier writings of Kaldor (1939) and Working (1949), this theory predicts that futures prices
reect the cost of purchasing and storing the underlying commodity until the contracts
maturity. Therefore, the cost of storage is perceived as the compensation to holders of
inventories to carry the commodity into the future and as such it affects futures pricing.
Following the work of Kaldor and Working, Brennan (1958) and Telser (1958)
formulated convenience yield as a negative function of the level of inventories. Recently,
following the same reasoning, Gorton, Hayashi, and Rouwenhorst (2013) treat convenience
Nikolaos Milonas is at National and Kapodistrian University of Athens, Athens, Greece. Nikolaos Paratsiokas
is at Institute of Economic and Industrial Research, Athens, Greece. The authors thank the participants of the
53rd Meeting of EWGCFM and the 2nd International Conference of RCEM at Chania, Greece, May 2224,
2014 and the participants of the World Finance Conference in Venice, July 24, 2014 for useful comments
on an earlier draft. The authors alone have the responsibility for any remaining errors.
JEL Classication: G12, G13
*Correspondence author, National and Kapodistrian University of Athens, 1 Sofokleous Street, 105 59 Athens,
Greece. Tel: þ30 210 3689442, Fax: þ30 210 3689468, e-mail: nmilonas@econ.uoa.gr
Received October 2015; Accepted July 2016
The Journal of Futures Markets, Vol. 37, No. 5, 522538 (2017)
© 2016 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Published online 25 August 2016 in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com).
DOI: 10.1002/fut.21807
yield as a negative function of the inventory level in equilibrium. Convenience yield arises in
the case of a stockoutof a commodity and represents the additional benet received by
inventory holders after accommodating for the cost of storage. In another model, Routlege,
Seppi, and Spatt (2000) treat convenience yield as a function of inventories and consider an
exogenous shock arising from an imbalance between demand and supply. This imbalance
leads to an option in the hands of the commodity holder to sell the commodity when supplies
are scarce.
The option-like feature of convenience yield has been analyzed in a number of papers
including Heaney (2002), Henkel, Howe, and Hughes (1990), and Milonas and Thomadakis
(1997a). These models introduce the contingent nature of convenience yield attributed to
the level of inventories which, under various exogenous circumstances, may fall at low levels
that cannot meet current demand. To restore the demand/supply equilibrium, spot prices
increase above futures prices giving rise to convenience yields. In this case, the convenience
yield becomes in-the-money.At other times with ample inventories to meet current
demand, convenience yields are nil and become out-of-the money.
Convenience yields have been documented empirically in a number of studies. Fama
and French (1987) examined 21 commodities in the period 19661984 focusing on the
futures basis and futures risk premium. They found large variation of the basis due to changes
in interest rates and seasonality from which they inferred the existence of convenience yields.
Direct evidence that convenience yields have the characteristics of call options was provided
by Milonas and Thomadakis (1997b). The empirical evidence on corn, wheat, soybeans, and
copper over the period 19661995 shows the existence of convenience yields in direct
positive relationship with the volatility of spot prices and negative relationship with the level
of inventories.
Milonas and Henker (2001) examined the prices of Brent and WTI crude oils in the
period 19911995 and veried the positive relationship between convenience yield and spot
price volatility and the negative relationship with oil stocks. The authors found that
convenience yield estimates are signicant portions of cash prices exceeding 2%, on average.
While the vast majority on commodity literature agrees on the importance and
applicability of the theory of storage and the existence of convenience yield in storable
commodities, concrete evidence in the case of non-storable commodities, like electricity, has
not been established yet.
Regarding electricity prices, Bessembinder and Lemmon (2002), Eydeland and Geman
(1998), Lucia and Schwartz (2002), and Pirrong and Jermakyan (2008) argued that due to
the non-storable nature of electricity, the cost-of-carry theory and the implied arbitrage
arguments are not applicable. Instead, they decompose futures electricity prices into the
expected spot price at delivery and the involved risk premium. Empirical studies by Cartea
and Villaplana (2008), Furio and Meneu (2010), and Longstaff and Wang (2004) employing
data of spot and futures prices from different power exchange markets, conrm the existence
of statistically signicant risk premia that exhibit high volatility and regular changes in sign.
Other studies by Clewlow and Strickland (2000), Geman and Roncoroni (2006), and
Huisman and de Jong (2003) consider the term structure of electricity futures prices as
depending on the properties of the spot price such as its stochastic volatility, price jumps and
mean reversion. Yet, in doing so, they do not account for the potential impact of fuel inventory
levels on the electricity futures prices.
Two studies on electricity prices depart from previous research by taking the approach
of incorporating the fuels supply into the behavior of electricity prices. In this context,
Douglas and Popova (2008) accounted for the amount of natural gas in storage as a
determinant of the risk premium in futures electricity markets. In a similar approach,
Botterud et al. (2010) studied the impact of the level of water reserves on spot and futures
Convenience Yields in Electricity Prices 523

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT