Congressional Vote Options

Date01 August 2003
AuthorDAVID C. KING,RICHARD J. ZECKHAUSER
Published date01 August 2003
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.3162/036298003X200935
387Congressional Vote Options
LEGISLATIVE STUDIES QUARTERLY, XXVIII, 3, August 2003 387
DAVID C. KING
RICHARD J. ZECKHAUSER
Harvard University
Congressional Vote Options
Numerous accounts reveal that congressional leaders often secure “hip-pocket
votes” or “if you need me” pledges from rank-and-file legislators. These are essen-
tially options on votes. Leaders exercise sufficient options—pay legislators to convert
to favorable votes—when those options will yield victory. Otherwise, they release
the options. A model shows that this optimal strategy for leaders produces many
small victories, few small losses, and losses that are, on average, larger than victories.
We find precisely these patterns, hence strong evidence for vote options, in Congres-
sional Quarterly key votes from 1975 through 2001 and in non-key votes from the
106th Congress (1999–2000).
Introduction
On June 20, 2001, the House of Representatives took up a supple-
mental appropriations bill. President George W. Bush, having signed a
large tax cut package a few days earlier, strongly favored a controversial
provision to spend $30.5 million on mailings that would tell taxpayers a
rebate check was in the offing. David Obey (D-WI) offered an amend-
ment to spend the money on drug-trafficking programs instead. The
official record from that vote shows that President Bush and the House
Republican leadership won, defeating Obey’s proposal 216 to 212 (Parks
2001), but that narrow tally tells only part of the story. Six Republicans
changed their votes from “yes” to “no” as the Republican leadership
extended the time for voting. In those closing minutes, Republican
leaders called in “if you need me” pledges from wavering members
while full-throated Democrats chanted “shame, shame, shame.” If
changing or delaying one’s vote in response to a promise from the
leadership is a real shame, then it is widely shared.
Marjorie Margolies-Mezvinsky (D-PA), for example, cast the
deciding vote on President Clinton’s 1993 budget-reconciliation bill. As
the last legislator to vote on August 5, 1993, the outcome was hers to
determine, and most observers expected a “no” vote. Margolies-
Mezvinsky voted “yes” instead. Congressional Quarterly tells the
story: “She had pledged during her campaign and even the day before
388 David C. King and Richard J. Zeckhauser
the vote that she would vote against a bill that increased taxes. But
Democratic leaders extracted a private promise from her to support
the deficit-reduction package if her vote proved necessary to pass it”
(CQ Almanac 1993, C39). This was a classic “if you need me” pledge,
which we shall label an “option.” Although it was widely predicted that
the tax package would be handily defeated, President Clinton and House
leaders got matters close enough that calling in the option on Margolies-
Mezvinsky’s vote was worthwhile; the bill triumphed by a single vote.
The literature on presidential leadership is rich (Bond and Fleisher
1990; Covington 1987, 1988; de Marchi and Sullivan 1998; Edwards
1989; Kernell 1993; Moe and Howell 1999; Peterson 1990; Sullivan
1987, 1990a, 1990b; Rivers and Rose 1985). Likewise, insightful scholar-
ship has addressed the role of coalition leaders in Congress (Baron and
Ferejohn 1989; Carrubba and Volden 2000; Cooper and Brady 1981;
Dodd 1983; Fiorina and Shepsle 1989; Groseclose and Snyder 1996;
Sinclair 1995; Snyder 1991). None of these models includes what is at
the heart of the Obey and the Margolies-Mezvinsky stories. Yet the
story is common in legislatures, where the art of politics is deft coalition
building and “if you need me” pledges are critical building blocks.
This paper employs a simple, nonformal model to introduce the
concept of securing options on votes. In brief, leaders build coalitions
that are “close enough” to make it worthwhile to call in pledges from
cross-pressured members. In most legislatures, coalition leaders rarely
buy votes outright at the moment they need them, as consumers buy
apples or candy bars. Rather, legislative leaders purchase “hip-pocket”
votes or “if you need me” pledges, which are options on votes to be
called in if and when needed.
President Clinton saw several “narrow victory” coalitions unravel.
Few were more embarrassing than the defeat he suffered on the 1994
Omnibus Crime Bill.1 On a critical procedural vote, White House Chief
of Staff Leon Panetta boldly predicted victory (“we’re going to kick
some ass” was his delicate phrasing), but the president lost by 15 votes
in the House. A hoped-for win turned out to be a big loss. Why? “Several
members who had been willing to support the leadership if needed
instead voted no when it became clear the [measure] would not pass,”
explain Idelson and Sammon (1994, 52). President Clinton did not get
the vote close enough to make it worthwhile to call in the “if you need
me” pledges (i.e., to exercise the vote options) he had spent the previous
week securing.
When coalition leaders do secure sufficient votes to win, excess
vote options will not be exercised. Washington Democrat Norm Dicks
said as much to John Kasich (R-OH) and Ron Dellums (D-CA) on

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT