Condorcet Loser in 2016: Apparently Trump; Condorcet Winner: Not Clinton?
Author | Richard F. Potthoff,Michael C. Munger |
DOI | 10.1177/1532673X211009499 |
Published date | 01 November 2021 |
Date | 01 November 2021 |
https://doi.org/10.1177/1532673X211009499
American Politics Research
2021, Vol. 49(6) 618 –636
© The Author(s) 2021
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/1532673X211009499
journals.sagepub.com/home/apr
Article
Introduction
Legitimacy, transparency, and accuracy are crucial features
of any social choice process. In selecting chief executives,
where the winner affects the future of the courts, public pol-
icy, and bureaucratic personnel, these three factors are even
more important. But legitimacy is conferred by conformity
with existing rules. Transparency requires that rules are
simple, and cause-and-effect relations are clear. Accuracy
requires some consensus that the “best” candidate was
selected, in effect assuming that there is an underlying
shared ranking of alternatives. In the past five years, many
U.S. citizens (Reinhart, 2020) seem to have developed a
sense that the current process of selecting our executive in
effect exhibits none of the three crucial features we have
listed.
In this paper we offer an assessment of the 2016 U.S.
presidential election,1 as a means of gauging the long-term
stress that our electoral system may be under. There have
already been critiques, both in scholarly forums (e.g.,
Muirhead & Rosenblum, 2019) and in the popular press
(e.g., Beinart, 2016), raising questions about the transpar-
ency and legitimacy of the 2016 result, given the complexity
of the Electoral College and the substantial margin by which
Donald Trump lost the popular vote. The attacks on the
legitimacy of elections and the way votes are counted in the
aftermath of the 2020 election have made a descriptive
understanding of this subject even more urgent.
Our focus is on accuracy, because (1) it is the quality most
plausibly subject to scientific evaluation, and (2) a system
that is perceived as inaccurate is likely to fail on grounds of
legitimacy and transparency as well. The specific criterion
we use to evaluate accuracy is venerable—the Condorcet
principle. Modern social choice theorists often employ the
notion of a Condorcet winner (or Condorcet candidate): a
candidate who would defeat all other candidates in pairwise
elections. If a Condorcet winner exists, there is a determinate
answer to the “which candidate is best?” question, at least in
the view of Condorcet himself.2 The Condorcet principle
simply states that if there is a Condorcet winner in the set of
alternatives, that candidate should be selected. Most theorists
would concur with this.3
In spite of this (near) consensus among experts, recogni-
tion of the value of the Condorcet principle is sorely defi-
cient among opinion leaders, the media establishment, and
non-specialist academicians and educators in evaluating the
Electoral College. The chance that a candidate might lose the
popular vote but still win in the Electoral College has—
deservedly—received much attention. But, we claim that it is
1009499APRXXX10.1177/1532673X211009499American Politics ResearchPottho and Munger
research-article2021
1Duke University, Durham, NC, USA
Corresponding Author:
Michael C. Munger, Department of Political Science and Department of
Economics, Duke University, Gross Hall, Durham, NC 27708-0204, USA.
Email: munger@duke.edu
Condorcet Loser in 2016: Apparently
Trump; Condorcet Winner: Not Clinton?
Richard F. Potthoff1 and Michael C. Munger1
Abstract
Using thermometer score data from the ANES, we show that while there may have been no clear-cut Condorcet winner
among the 2016 US presidential candidates, there appears to have been a Condorcet loser: Donald Trump. Thus the surprise
is that the electorate preferred not only Hillary Clinton, but also the two “minor” candidates, Gary Johnson and Jill Stein, to
Trump. Another surprise is that Johnson may have been the Condorcet winner. A minimal normative standard for evaluating
voting systems is advanced, privileging those systems that select Condorcet winners if one exists, and critiquing systems that
allow the selection of Condorcet losers. A variety of voting mechanisms are evaluated using the 2016 thermometer scores:
Condorcet voting, plurality, Borda, (single winner) Hare, Coombs, range voting, and approval voting. We conclude that the
essential problem with the existing voting procedure—Electoral College runoff of primary winners of two major parties—is
that it (demonstrably) allows the selection of a Condorcet loser.
Keywords
Condorcet winner, elections, social choice, U.S. politics
Potthoff and Munger 619
a mistake to ignore the more normatively and practically
grounded Condorcet principle and its ramifications. We
demonstrate that the current electoral system for American
presidents can, and in 2016 possibly did, select the least-
preferred of a set of four candidates.
To accomplish this, we propose a simple, and (we think)
uncontroversial, extension to the Condorcet principle. Let us
define a Condorcet loser as a candidate who loses, or would
lose, to each other candidate in a two-way match against
each. Then the principle is the mirror of the positive claim
above: If a Condorcet loser exists, no accurate voting aggre-
gation mechanism should select that candidate. The implica-
tion of such an analysis is then that any vote aggregation
procedure that selects a Condorcet-loser candidate is in seri-
ous need of reform.4
To conduct the analysis, we follow Abramson et al.
(1995) and Abramson et al. (2002, pp. 127–128) using the
feeling-thermometer data from the 2016 American National
Election Studies (ANES)5 pre- and post-election surveys.
ANES respondents provide such data by rating each candi-
date from 0° (“Very cold or unfavorable feeling”) to 100°
(“Very warm or favorable feeling”).
Respondents who give candidate X a higher thermometer
rating than Y are presumed to prefer X to Y, and would vote
for X over Y in a (hypothetical) two-way race with only that
pair of candidates on the ballot.6 From these thermometer
scores we are therefore able to construct lists for each voter,
from most-preferred to least-preferred candidates.
Our conclusion is that, among the candidates for whom
we have usable data, Donald Trump was a Condorcet loser.7
This is saying something other than simply that his victory
was the result of a particular configuration of rules and cir-
cumstances. That is not surprising, and is in fact well known
already, since Trump lost the popular vote. What is surpris-
ing is that the election process would select a Condorcet-
loser candidate, a striking signal of deep pathology, and a
new reason to consider reform.
The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 reviews some
normative considerations for “good” electoral institu-
tions. Section 3 presents the Condorcet results for the 2016
election.8 We use the ANES thermometer data in Section 4
to project (disregarding the Electoral College) how the 2016
election results could have fared under different voting sys-
tems—plurality, Borda, (single-winner) Hare, Coombs,
range voting, and approval voting, in addition to our main
interest, the Condorcet system. Section 5 examines possible
relations of single-peaked preferences to placement of 2016
presidential candidates along a spectrum. In Section 6 we
apply principal component analysis to respondents’ answers
to some ANES policy questions and then consider its rele-
vance to our results. Section 7 points to some auxiliary anal-
yses. Different aspects of thermometer scores receive
consideration in Section 8. Section 9 concludes.
Before proceeding to the analysis, it is useful to issue a
general methodological caveat. A variety of objections
might be raised that the 2016 election was peculiar, and in
particular that the degree of negative partisanship was so
extreme that the particular approach of using the compari-
son of thermometer scores on the ANES for comparative
candidate evaluation is suspect. We consider a number of
such objections in Section 8, and the associated Notes for
Section 8 in the Supplemental Appendix. But there are two
general points that can be usefully raised at the outset. First,
this use of thermometer scores has been used by other schol-
ars in the past, for just this purpose (e.g., as early as Brams
& Merrill, 1994).
Second, there is no reason to think that the effects of nega-
tive partisanship are limited to the way respondents fill out
the ANES. It is certainly true that a large number of (appar-
ent) Trump supporters gave Clinton a 0° rating, and that
(apparent) Clinton supporters gave Trump a 0º rating. But we
contend that it was more, rather than less, likely that this
thermometer evaluation would have carried through to actual
voting intentions, and to voting behavior [in (hypothetical)
two-way races; or, more realistically, with ranked ballots],
precisely because negative partisanship was so intense in
2016. There are good reasons to be skeptical that the relative
magnitudes of thermometer scores predict actual binary vot-
ing intentions perfectly, but there is no reason to believe that
this problem was worse in 2016 than in other years, and we
do go to some lengths to investigate possible issues with this
approach in Section 8.
It is important to note, however, that there may have been
at least two reasons to see the “third-party” candidates in
2016 as unusual. First, while many Americans express a
vague desire for “more choice” or “a third party” in most
elections, that preference has been on the increase since 2013
(Jones, 2021). Consequently, while subjects may express a
preference for third-party candidates, the size of this effect
may be magnified by the generic dissatisfaction with the
choices offered by the two legacy parties.
Second, though Stein and (especially) Johnson had some
visibility and political achievements prior to the election, the
level of well-informed opinions of respondents was likely
less than in previous studies of third-party candidates—as
reflected, perhaps, by high levels of 50° (neutral) thermom-
eter scores for Stein and Johnson and of respondents’ failures
to rate them (which we cover in more detail later). On the
other hand, George Wallace, Ross Perot, and Ralph Nader
(for example) had substantial national reputations, and name
recognition, before the election or were able to use advertis-
ing or (in the case of Perot) debate participation to develop
an independent status as candidates on their own. The empir-
ical effect of this difference is not clear; it is possible that,
particularly for an office as important as president, any ambi-
guity, in respondents’ minds, about Stein and Johnson was a
drawback without which the thermometer scores for them
would have been even higher. But it is also at least possible
that the more “generic third-party” status of Stein and
Johnson was inflated in thermometer scores, and the vote
Get this document and AI-powered insights with a free trial of vLex and Vincent AI
Get Started for FreeStart Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting
