Competitive Permit Markets and Vertical Structures: The Relevance of Imperfectly Competitive Eco‐Industries

Published date01 February 2014
AuthorHUBERT STAHN,SONIA SCHWARTZ
Date01 February 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12048
COMPETITIVE PERMIT MARKETS AND VERTICAL
STRUCTURES:THE RELEVANCE OF IMPERFECTLY
COMPETITIVE ECO-INDUSTRIES
SONIA SCHWARTZ
CERDI, Universit´
e d’Auvergne
HUBERT STAHN
Aix Marseille School of Economics, CNRS, EHESS
Abstract
Permit markets lead polluting firms to purchase abatement
goods from an eco-industry which is often concentrated.
This paper studies the consequences of this sort of imper-
fectly competitive eco-industry on the equilibrium choices
of the competitive polluting firms. It then characterizes the
second-best pollution cap. By comparing this situation to
one of perfect competition, we show that Cournot compe-
tition on the abatement good market contributes not only
to a nonoptimal level of emission reduction but also to a
higher permit price, which reduces the production level.
These distortions increase with market power, measured by
the margin taken by the noncompetitive firms, and suggest
a second-best larger pollution cap.
1. Introduction
Since the U.S. Acid Rain Program, an increasing number of countries
have opted for pollution permit markets to address pollution problems. In
particular, the European Union Emission Trading Scheme (EU ETS) was
Sonia Schwartz, Universit´
e d’Auvergne, 65 boulevard Franc¸ois Mitterand, 63000 Clermont-
Ferrand, France (sonia.schwartz@udamail.fr). Hubert Stahn, Aix Marseille School of
Economics, Chˆ
ateau Lafarge, route des Milles, 13210 Les Milles, France (hubert.stahn@
univ-amu.fr).
This work was supported by the Agence Nationale de la Recherche of the French gov-
ernment through the program Investissements d’avenir (ANR-10-LABX-14-01). We are
grateful for helpful comments from anonymous reviewers.
Received May 6, 2011; Accepted November 23, 2011.
C2013 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Public Economic Theory, 16 (1), 2014, pp. 69–95.
69
70 Journal of Public Economic Theory
implemented in 2005 and the Kyoto Protocol establishing an international
carbon market came into force in 2006. Both are intended to fight global
warming. The EU ETS, for instance, covers over 11,500 energy intensive
installations representing nearly half of the EU’s emissions of carbon diox-
ide (Ellerman, Convery, Buchner, and Carraro 2007; Ellerman, Convery, and
De Pertuis, 2010).
Since the seminal contributions of Crocker (1966)andDales(1968), it is
well known that by setting a price signal for pollution, this kind of instrument
encourages polluting firms to reduce their emissions by purchasing abate-
ment goods and services. This specific demand appeared notably with the
Acid Rain Program (Joskow, Schmalensee, and Bailey 1998), which has led
coal-fired power stations to invest heavily in scrubbers, a technology allow-
ing for reduction in sulfur emissions.1More recently, the EU ETS has led to
annual spending for pollution reduction representing 2.9–3.7 billion, also
mainly invested in abatement goods and services. And this demand grows
quickly, since firms must comply with more and more stringent environmen-
tal policies. This phenomenon largely contributes to the development of an
“eco-industry”2supplying these products to polluting firms.
This new industry covers pollution and resource management activities,
ranging from the development of clean technologies to the optimization of
methods for monitoring and managing environmental impacts. From that
point of view, the eco-industry represents one of the biggest industrial sec-
tors: since 2005, it matches the aerospace and pharmaceutical sectors in size.
However, these activities often remain highly concentrated. Vivendi Environ-
ment and Ond´
eo (Suez Lyonnaise des eaux) are, for instance, the inter-
national leaders in wastewater treatment. Even in the more general waste
treatment sector, the key players CGEA-Onyx, Sarp, Dalkia, Sita, and Elyo
are easily identified. The air treatment sector, in which the French firm LAB
is the European leader, seems more competitive, but cooperation with the
French firm CNIM (Constructions Industrielles de la M´
editerran´
ee) may
change this situation.
This suggests that perfect competition is an unsuitable assumption for
modeling an “eco-industry.” Besides, Perino (2010b) provides empirical evi-
dence that eco-industry charges mark-ups and that their size depends on the
choice and stringency of environmental regulation. In this case, it is obvious
that the abatement good price does not completely reflect its marginal cost.
This clearly affects the decision of the polluting firms, i.e., their production
1Scrubber systems are a diverse group of air pollution control devices that can be used to
remove some particulates and/or gases from industrial exhaust streams. Flue-gas desulfu-
rization devices have high removal rates of up to 98%.
2This notion was introduced in an OECD report (1999). It consists of activities that mea-
sure, prevent, limit, minimize, or correct environmental damages. The reader is also re-
ferred to Sinclair-Desgagn´
e(2008) for historical facts in Europe and North America or to
the European Commission reports (Ernst and Young 2006, European Commission 1999,
2007, 2009).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT