Competitive intelligence and disclosure

Date01 October 2015
AuthorSusan G. Watts,Mark Bagnoli
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12103
Published date01 October 2015
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.46, No. 4, Winter 2015
pp. 709–729
Competitive intelligence and disclosure
Mark Bagnoli
and
Susan G. Watts
Competitive intelligence (CI) activities open new opportunities for firms to acquire and disclose
information. We show that disclosure depends on the relative usefulness of information to the
competing firms and is generally less (more) likely with Cournot (Bertrand) competition and
when firms adopt product differentiationstrategies. When CI costs are independent of information
characteristics, each firm seeks information solely useful to itself and discloses it unless it is a
Bertrand competitor with customer information. Only when the cost advantage is sufficiently
great does each firm seek information useful to itself and its rival.
1. Introduction
In recent years, firms have invested heavily in competitive intelligence (CI) activities.1
These activities are focused on developing systems to generate information and insight about a
firm’s rivals, the firm’s own customers or production costs, and, when necessary, processes for
maintaining secrecy. Much of the focus is on learning and analyzing rival business strategies and
developing appropriate responses, but significant effort is also expended studying the firm’s and
its rivals’ customers and production processes.2As a concrete example, consider the European
unit of Cisco Systems’ adoption of a CI system.3Cisco’s initial CI efforts focused on developing
systems to acquire information about their current customers, industry demand more broadly,
macroeffects on industry demand, and demand for future product characteristics. Subsequently,
Cisco expanded its CI activities to include developing systems to acquire information about
Purdue University; mbagnoli@purdue.edu, swatts@purdue.edu.
We thank the Editor,Kathr yn Spier,and two anonymous referees for many helpful comments and suggestions. We also
thank Jennifer Altamuro, Anil Arya, Masako Darrough, Dick Dietrich, John Fellingham, Leslie Hodder, Pat Hopkins,
Rick Johnston, Ranjani Krishnan, Brian Mittendorf, Marc Picconi, Doug Schroeder, Isabel Wang,Rick Young, workshop
participants at The Ohio State University, participants at the August 2011 American Accounting Association annual
meeting in Denver,CO, and our discussant Leonidas Enrique de la Rosa for helpful discussions. Wegratefully acknowledge
the financial support provided by the Krannert Graduate School of Management and Purdue University.
1Fuld(2007) repor ts on the first survey of CI expendituresand estimates that Fortune 1000 firms spent approximately
$1 billion in 2006 with the expectation that they would grow tenfold by2012.
2Standard references to CI activities include Prescott and Miller (2001), Carr (2003), Fuld (2006), Liebowitz
(2006), Davenport and Harris (2007), Fleisher and Bensoussan (2007), and Ayers(2008).
3Details are from an interview of Joost Drieman, Market Intelligence Director Europe (Global Intelligence Alliance,
2008).
C2015, The RAND Corporation. 709
710 / THE RAND JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
its competitors and information about its own and its competitors’ selling channels with the
intention of acquiring information about the costs of servicing customers.4Interestingly, Cisco’s
Chief Executive Officer, John Chambers, is well known for the quantity and quality of his
voluntary disclosures about product prices, revenues, costs, product development, and general
market conditions provided in the firm’s quarterly earnings press releases, conference calls, and
8-K filings.
The objectives of this article are to extend our understanding of ex ante disclosure policy
choices to information environments that more closely capture the impact of corporate CI ac-
tivities and to study the firms’ strategic incentives to direct those activities to acquire specific
information characteristics and create the resulting equilibrium information environment. We
expect CI activities to produce information structures that differ from those examined previously
in, for example, Gal-Or (1985, 1986), Darrough (1993), and Raith (1996), among others. This
literature examines the private values case, when a firm has private information about its own
production costs, and the common values case, when a firm has private information about a
demand parameter that impacts its own and its rival’s payoffs symmetrically.5We generalize the
information structure to an intermediate values case in which the information is privately useful
to the firm and (at least) partially useful to its rival.
Our generalized information structure leads to disclosure policy choices that are quite
different from those in the prior literature. The most familiar result from this work, often referred
to as the “flipping result,” is that Cournot (Bertrand) competitors adopt a policy of disclosure
(nondisclosure) when theyhave private information about costs but adopt a policy of not disclosing
(disclosing) when they have private information about a common demand parameter (Gal-Or,
1985, 1986; Darrough, 1993). Further, in the private and common values cases, the firms have
a dominant strategy that does not depend on the degree of product heterogeneity or the firms’
underlying level of uncertainty.6
In contrast, in the intermediate values information structure that we introduce, each firm
adopts a policy of disclosure for some sets of information characteristics and a policy of nondis-
closure for others, regardless of whether firms have privateinfor mation about customers or costs
and regardless of whether they are Cournot or Bertrand competitors. Specifically,when firms are
Cournot competitors, a firm adopts an ex ante policy of disclosure if its private information is
sufficiently asymmetrically useful to itself and its rival. In contrast, when the firms are Bertrand
competitors, a firm adopts an ex ante policy of disclosure if its private information about cus-
tomers is sufficiently useful to itself and its rival or if its private information is about costs and is
sufficiently useful to the firm itself. Thus, in general, for parameters for which disclosure occurs
when firms are Bertrand competitors (usually thought of as highly competitive markets), it does
not occur when the firms are Cournot competitors (usually thought of as less competitive mar-
kets), and vice versa. That is, disclosure depends on the information characteristics and whether
the products are strategic substitutes or strategic complements.
An examination of the intermediate values information structure that we introduce also
provides insight into how the degree of product differentiation affects disclosure policy choices.
We show that for Cournot competitors disclosure of either customer or cost information is more
likely in more homogeneous product markets. However, for Bertrand competitors, customer in-
formation is less likely and cost information is more likely to be disclosed in more homogeneous
product markets. Together, these results suggest an empirical regularity that disclosure is generally
less (more) likely in less (more) competitive markets when firms adopt differentiation strategies.
4A very similar pattern in CI activities is described by Rene Loozen, Business Intelligence Manager for Royal
Vopak(Global Intelligence Alliance, 2009).
5Raith (1996) introduces imperfect signals and shows how a firm’s disclosure policy is affected by the quality of
its signal and how correlated the signals the firms receive are.
6These results depend on the assumption that each firm makes its disclosure policy choice independently. If the
firms are permitted to use “quid pro quo” disclosure policies, the “flipping result” no longer characterizes equilibrium
disclosure activity (Kirby,1988; Malueg and Tsutsui, 1998a).
C
The RAND Corporation 2015.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT