Competitive cross‐subsidization

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12293
Published date01 September 2019
AuthorZhijun Chen,Patrick Rey
Date01 September 2019
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.50, No. 3, Fall 2019
pp. 645–665
Competitive cross-subsidization
Zhijun Chen
and
Patri ck Rey∗∗
Cross-subsidization arises naturally when firms with different comparative advantages compete
for consumers with heterogeneous shopping patterns. Firms then face a form of co-opetition,
as they offer substitutes for one-stop shoppers and complements for multi-stop shoppers. When
intense competition for one-stop shoppers drives total prices down to cost, firms subsidize weak
products with the profits made on strong products. Moreover, firms have incentives to seek
comparative advantages on different products. Finally, banning below-cost pricing increases
firms’ profits at the expense of one-stop shoppers, which calls for a cautious use of below-cost
pricing regulations in competitive markets.
1. Introduction
Multiproduct firms compete using a variety of pricing strategies. One commonly observed
strategy is cross-subsidization, in which firms price some products below cost and compensate
the resulting loss with profits from other products. Competition between Apple and Amazon
in e-book and tablet computer markets offers an illustration. In 2010, Amazon was selling the
“Kindle Fire” below cost,1while Apple preloaded 30,000 books free of charge on the iBooks
store.2It was commonly recognized that Apple’s iPad offered more functions than the Kindle
Fire, whereas Amazon—with more than two million e-books—provided more variety and thus a
higher match value than the iBooks store. Hence, each firm had a comparatively stronger product
in relation to its rival. Furthermore, both firms were selling their comparatively weaker products
Monash University; chenzj1219@gmail.com.
∗∗University of Toulouse Capitole; patrick.rey@tse-fr.eu.
Weare g rateful to Luis Cabral, Arthur Cazaubiel, Stephen Hamilton, Alessandro Iara, and Paul Klemperer,as well as to
participants at the EARIE conference, the IIOC conference, the conference of the German Economic Association, the ACE
conference, and the seminars at the University of Aukland, the Universityof Melbour ne, the NHH, Monash University,
Singapore Management University, the Toulouse School of Economics, the Paris School of Economics, and CREST
for helpful comments. Financial support from the European Research Council (ERC) under the European Community’s
Seventh FrameworkProgramme (FP7/2007–2013) Grant Agreement N 340903, is also g ratefullyacknowledged.
1The Kindle Fire, which offered access to the Amazon Appstore, streaming movies, and TV shows, was
sold in the United States. at a retail price of $199. Amazon’s hardware cost for a Kindle Fire was estimated
at $201.70, not including “additional expenses such as software, licensing, royalties, or other expenditures.” See:
technology.ihs.com/389433/amazon-kindle-fire-costs-20170-to-manufacture.
2See AppleInsider’s report, available at: appleinsider.com/articles/10/03/25/apple_loads_up_new_ibooks_store_
with_free_public_domain_ipad_titles.
C2019, The RAND Corporation. 645
646 / THE RAND JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
below cost, and deriving profits from their strong products.3Moreover, consumers could combine
the two firms’ strong products, but not the weak ones: iPad users could download a free Kindle
Application to access Amazon’s e-books, whereas Kindle Fire users had no option to access the
iBooks store.
This strategy in competitive markets, such as tablets and e-books, is somewhat at odds with
the existing theory. According to this theory, cross-subsidization arises in the context of regulated
or monopolistic markets,4or in markets characterized by friction, such as consumers’ limited
information or bounded rationality (see the literature review below). Here, we develop a new
approach, based on the diversity of purchasing patterns.
The literature on competitive multiproduct pricing often assumes that customers engage in
“one-stop shopping” and purchase all products from the same supplier. Yet, in practice, many
customers engage in multi-stop shopping and rely on several suppliers to fulfill their needs. The
choice between these purchasing patterns is driven not onlyby the diversity and the relative merits
of suppliers’ offerings, but also by the transaction costs that buyers must bear in order to enjoy
the products. As mentioned by Klemperer (1992), these transaction costs include physical costs,
such as transportation costs, and nonphysical costs, such as the opportunity cost of time and the
adoption cost of using a new electronic device. Following the terminology of the literature, we
will refer to these costs as “shopping costs.” Obviously, these costs vary across customers. For
example, some consumers may face tighter time constraints and/or dislike shopping, whereas
others may be less time-constrained and/or enjoy shopping. Indeed, some users, already familiar
with the Kindle system, may be reluctant to switch to the iPad because of the associated learning
costs,5whereas others may enjoy the adoption of a new device. All other things being equal,
customers with high transaction costs tend to favor “one-stop shopping,” whereas others prefer
“multi-stop shopping.”
We first note that the diversity of purchasing patterns gives rise to a form of “co-opetition”:
on the one hand, firms offer substitutes for one-stop shoppers, who look for the best basket
of products; on the other hand, firms offer complements for multi-stop shoppers, who seek to
combine suppliers’ best products. We show that this duality drastically affects firms’ pricing
strategies and can lead to cross-subsidization, even in competitive markets.
Specifically, we consider a setting in which two firms offer the same product line (which
consists of two products, for simplicity). Consumers are perfectly informed about prices, as
is indeed the case for e-books and tablets. To discard price-discrimination motives, we further
assume that consumers have inelastic demands. Altogether,these assumptions allow us to abstract
from the motivations already highlighted in the literature on cross-subsidization (see the literature
review below). Our key ingredients are instead that: (i) consumers have heterogeneous shopping
costs; and (ii) through lower costs and/or higher consumer value, each firm enjoysa comparative
advantage overone product. For the sake of exposition, we initially assume that firms have similar
comparative advantages; that is, each firm has a stronger product than its rival, but overall, their
baskets generate the same surplus. In equilibrium, consumers with high shopping costs engage
in one-stop shopping, and competition for these consumers drives firms’ aggregate prices down
to cost. By contrast, consumers with low shopping costs engage in multi-stop shopping and buy
each firm’s strong product; thus, the firms make a profit. Cross-subsidization therefore arises
naturally, with each firm pricing its weak product below cost and subsidizing the resulting loss
with the profit from its strong product.
3Before 2010, Amazon wasalso selling newly released e-books below cost. However,prices were raised after Apple
proposed the controversial “agency model” for e-books. More recently, Amazon has introduced a more sophisticated
version of its reader (e.g., the Oasis), which offers additional features. Still, the pattern of cross-subsidizing weaker
products with stronger ones appears to have persisted from 2010 to 2016.
4For instance, Faulhaber(2005) asser ts that “under competitiveconditions, the issue of cross-subsidy simply does
not arise.”
5Before the launch of the iPad and the Kindle Fire, readers of Amazon’s e-books were mainly using the original
Kindle device.
C
The RAND Corporation 2019.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT