Competition and subsidies in the deregulated US local telephone industry

AuthorMo Xiao,Ying Fan
Published date01 October 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12109
Date01 October 2015
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.46, No. 4, Winter 2015
pp. 751–776
Competition and subsidies in the deregulated
US local telephone industry
Ying Fan
and
Mo Xiao∗∗
The 1996 Telecommunications Act opened the monopolistic US local telephone industry to
new entrants. However, substantial entry costs have prevented some markets from becoming
competitive. We study various subsidy policies designed to encourage entry.We estimate a dynamic
entry game using data on potential and actual entrants, allowing forheterogeneous option values
of waiting. We find that subsidies to smaller markets are more cost effective in reducingmonopoly
markets, but subsidies to only lower-cost firms are less cost effective than a nondiscriminatory
policy. Subsidies in only early periods reduce the option value of waiting and accelerate the
arrival of competition.
1. Introduction
Many telecommunication services have been deregulated in the last few decades, including
the US local telephone industry. Before deregulation, services were provided by regulated mo-
nopolists, competitive entry was forbidden, and prices were set by federal and state authorities
according to cost-plus, rate-of-return regulation guidelines (Hausman and Taylor, 2012). After
deregulation, the markets were opened to competition and many of the pricing regulations were
phased out. Consequently, on the one hand, smaller, competitive telecommunications compa-
nies were allowed to enter, even using the incumbents’ unbundled network and facilities; on the
other hand, incumbents enjoyed newfound freedom and greater market power if new entrants
did not arrive. Given the substantial cost of entry in the telecommunications industry, ensuring a
competitive market structure after deregulation is an ongoing concern for policy makers.
University of Michigan; yingfan@umich.edu.
∗∗University of Arizona; mxiao@eller.arizona.edu.
We thank Daniel Ackerberg, Steven Berr y, Juan Esteban Carranza, Gautam Gowrisankaran, Paul Grieco, Philip Haile,
Taylor Jaworski, Kai-Uwe K¨
uhn, Francine Lafontaine, Ariel Pakes, Mark Roberts, Marc Rysman, Gustavo Vicentini,
Jianjun Wu, Daniel Yi Xu, three anonymousreferees, and par ticipants of California Institute of Technology, the Federal
Trade Commission, Harvard University, IIOC 2011, the Pennsylvania State University, SED 2012, the University of
Alberta, the University of D¨
usseldorf, the University of Michigan, and Wayne State University for their constructive
comments. Wethank the NET Institute for financial suppor t.
C2015, The RAND Corporation. 751
752 / THE RAND JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS
In general, entry costs can hinder competition in a deregulated market. When the costs of
entry are high enough, deregulation itself may not be sufficientto attract entr y.The monopoly mar-
ket structure from before the deregulation might remain, only now the incumbent is unregulated
and may exploit its market power. To address this issue, one policy remedy could be to subsidize
new firms’ entry costs. Such subsidy policies have been adopted in many industries.1This opens
up the question of how to design such subsidies as a function of the economic environment. For
instance, different potential entrants may face different levelsof entr y costs. Also, markets differ
in size, which affects post entry profit. How important is it to consider such firm heterogeneity
and market heterogeneity in the design of the subsidy policy? In addition, although a subsidy
lowers a firm’s entry cost today, it also changes this firm’s belief about the future competition
level in the market it considers entering. How important is this competition effect for the design
of a subsidy policy?
In this article, we address the above questions by estimating a dynamic oligopoly game of
entry into the US local telephone industry. Prior to 1996, local markets were served by regulated
monopolists, the so-called Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers (ILECs), who were mostly Baby
Bell companies. After the 1996 Telecommunications Act (henceforth, the Act), the markets were
opened to new entrants, referred to as Competitive Local Exchange Carriers (CLECs). In this
study,we focus on facilities-based CLECs, which build their own fiber-optic networks and digital
switches2and are deemed by industry experts to represent true competition to ILECs (Crandell,
2001, 2005; Economides, 1999).3
We use a comprehensive panel data set, which records all facilities-based CLECs’ entry
decisions into local telephone markets between 1998 and 2002. With this data set, we observe
the identity of CLECs providing local telephone services to each local market each year. We also
observe the set of CLECs with certification to enter in each state each year. In this industry, a
CLEC needs to obtain certification from a state to operate in a market within the state. After
receiving state certification, a CLEC may wait years to actually enter. Based on this industry
feature, we define potential entrants into a local market as CLECs with certification from the
respective state. With information on the identity of potential and actual entrants, we are able
to observe how long a potential entrant waits to enter a market and several crucial firm-level
attributes associated with the cost of entry.
We set up a dynamic oligopoly game and incor porate the timing of entry and firm hetero-
geneity in the game. In our model, a potential entrant is a long-run player that decides whether
to enter or wait in each period. When making this decision, the potential entrant compares the
value of entry, minus entry costs, to the value of waiting. This is in contrast to most other en-
try studies, in which a firm either enters or perishes and the value of waiting is set to zero.4
Moreover, we allow potential entrants to be heterogeneous in entry costs. For example, a more
experienced potential entrant may face lower entry costs. To estimate our model, we follow the
recent development in two-step estimation strategies for dynamic oligopolyentr y games. That is,
we first obtain the conditional choice probabilities at each state from the data. We then match the
empirical conditional choice probability with its counterpart predicted by the model.
The estimation of the model gives results that are consistent with basic economic intuition.
For instance, we find that a CLEC’s post entry profit is decreasing in competition and increasing
1This practice is especially common in service industries, where the service is considered “essential for the basic
well-being of consumers.” Forexample, from 1978 to the present day, federal governmentprograms have subsidized entry
of dentists, physicians, and mental health specialists into geographic areas designated as Health Professional Shortage
Areas (Dunne, Klimek, Roberts, and Xu, 2013).
2Facilities-basedCLECs also lease some networks from ILECs to locations not served by the CLECs’ own networks;
and, more importantly,they need to interconnect with ILECs’ networks to exchange voice and data traffic.
3CLECs that resell ILECs’ service or CLECs that rent ILECs’ networks and provide value-added services only
yield thin profit margins. They are considered as unsustainable (Crandall, 2001).
4One exception is Fan (2006), who makes the distinction between a short-run and long-run player in a dynamic
entry game.
C
The RAND Corporation 2015.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT