Competing for Attention: Lobbying Time‐Constrained Politicians

AuthorCHRISTOPHER COTTON
Published date01 August 2016
Date01 August 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12202
COMPETING FOR ATTENTION:LOBBYING TIME-CONSTRAINED
POLITICIANS
CHRISTOPHER COTTON
Queen’s University
Abstract
We develop a model of lobbying in which a time and resource con-
strained policymaker first chooses which policy proposals to learn
about, before choosing which to implement. The policymaker reviews
the proposals of the interest groups who provide the highest contri-
butions. We study how policy outcomes and contributions depend on
policymaker constraints and the design of the “Contest for Attention.”
Among other results, awarding attention to the highest contributors
generally guarantees the first best policy outcome. It can also lead to
the highest possible contributions, suggesting that a policymaker may
not need to sacrifice policy in order to maximize contributions. Our
results also give insight into other settings where agents compete for a
decision maker’s attention.
“About all you get [in exchange for a contribution] is a chance to talk to
them.... If you have a good case you can win them over. But you have to be
able to talk to them.”
—Interest group representative interviewed in Herndon (1982, p. 1000)
“Access to the president should never be for sale.”
—Bob Edgar, president of Common Cause, February 26, 20131
1Common Cause is perhaps the most recognized U.S. organization focused on promoting campaign
finance reform. Edgar issued this statement in response to a New York Times article suggesting that Or-
ganizing for America, a nonprofit organization that developed from the Obama for America campaign
organization following the 2012 presidential elections, was selling access to the president.
Christopher Cotton, Department of Economics, Queen’s University, Kingston, Ontario K7L 3N6,
Canada (cotton@econ.queensu.ca).
This project benefited greatly from conversations with Steve Callander, Steve Coate, Ralph
Boleslavsky, David Kelly,Arnaud Dellis, and seminar participants at Queen’s University, Cornell Univer-
sity, Stanford GSB, University of Alberta, University of Miami, University of Pittsburgh, and University
of Padua, as well as the First Caribbean Game Theory Conference and the 2011 Tournaments, Contests
and Relative Performance Evaluation conference. The author is grateful for financial support provided
through his position as the Jarislowsky-Deutsch Chair in Economic and Financial Policy at Queen’s
University.
Received February 17, 2015; Accepted April 30, 2015.
C2016 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Public Economic Theory, 18 (4), 2016, pp. 642–665.
642
Competing for Attention 643
1. Introduction
Popular opinion is that political contributions corrupt policymaking. The majority of
Americans believe that “money buys results in Congress,” and that money biases legisla-
tion away from the needs of average constituents and in favor of deep-pocketed special
interests (Lessig 2011, p. 88). Theoretical models of politics largely support these pop-
ular views, with classic models depicting lobbying as little more than a quid pro quo ex-
change of political contributions for policy (e.g., Tullock 1980; Grossman and Helpman
1994). Insider accounts of policymaking, however, describe overtly corrupt behavior as
the rare exception, with most policymakers trying to do the right thing, while facing
severe constraints on their time and limits to their expertise (e.g., Bauer, Dexter, and
de Sola Pool 1963; Hansen 1991; Schram 1995; Baumgartner et al. 2009; Baumgartner
and Jones 2015). We present a model of the political process consistent with the insider
accounts of policymaking. Ours is a model of informational lobbying, where political
contributions help special interest groups (IGs) capture the attention of a time con-
strained policymaker, and are not provided in the direct exchange for policy favors. We
show how political contributions lead the policymaker to focus his efforts on the most
beneficial policies. By allocating his limited attention based on political contributions,
the policymaker can guarantee better policy outcomes than in the absence of contribu-
tions.
We develop a model of lobbying that approximates the political process described in
a number of insider accounts, which emphasize how severely constrained policymakers
are in their ability to learn about and implement policy proposals (e.g., Bauer et al.
1963; Hansen 1991; Baumgartner and Jones 2015). In our model, a policymaker faces
a number of policy proposals and must choose which to implement. The proposals
may involve earmark funding for projects within the policymaker’s home district. Due
to budget constraints, the policymaker may not be able to fund all of the projects he
believes are beneficial.2Alternatively, the proposals may involve introducing legislation
reforming policy on alternative issues. Drafting, introducing, and promoting legislation
is time-consuming, preventing the policymaker from introducing legislation in all areas
that may benefit his constituents. Although the proposals may not by nature be mutually
exclusive alternatives,3resource and time constraints necessitate that the policymaker
prioritize proposals and choose only some on which to focus his efforts.
Before choosing which proposals to implement, the policymaker can assess the costs
and benefits of alternative options by meeting with IGs and experts, reading government
reports or independent research, holding legislative hearings, or asking staff or govern-
ment agencies to research the political feasibility and constituent benefits of different
options.4If the policymaker carefully assesses all alternatives, then he can be certain
2Frisch and Kelly (2010, 2011) present evidence that during the 2006 budget cycle the Chairman of the
U.S. House Appropriations Subcommittee for Labor, Health and Human Services allowed each rank-
and-file member of the U.S. House to request up to $400,000 in earmark funding from his subcom-
mittee. The allotted amount increased systematically for subcommittee members, principals in at-risk
districts and those in leadership positions. If a legislator requested a larger amount of funding from the
subcommittee, the funding was rejected or cut down to the allotted amount. This process means that
legislators must carefully decide for which earmark proposals to request funding, and the legislators
may rely on political contributions to help narrow down the set of candidates.
3The policymaker could, if budgets permitted, fund many projects, and could, if time permitted, draft,
introduce, and pass legislation reforming many issues.
4See, for example, Baumgartner et al. (2009, p. 7) who observe: “In the case of Congress and adminis-
trative agencies, policymakers must choose to allocate their time among the myriad of different issues
they are called upon to address.”

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT