Comparative risk aversion in two periods: An application to self‐insurance and self‐protection

Published date01 March 2022
AuthorTobias Huber
Date01 March 2022
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jori.12353
Journal of Risk and Insurance. 2022;89:97130. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/JORI
|
97
Received: 15 September 2019
|
Revised: 14 February 2021
|
Accepted: 29 May 2021
DOI: 10.1111/jori.12353
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Comparative risk aversion in two periods:
An application to selfinsurance and
selfprotection
Tobias Huber
Institute for Risk Management and
Insurance, Munich Risk and Insurance
Center, LudwigMaximiliansUniversität
München, Munich, Germany
Correspondence
Tobias Huber, Institute for Risk
Management and Insurance, Munich
Risk and Insurance Center, Ludwig
MaximiliansUniversität München,
GeschwisterSchollPlatz 1, 80539
Munich, Germany.
Email: tobias.huber@lmu.de
Abstract
Risk management decisions provide a means to elicit
individuals' risk preferences empirically. In such a
context, the literature often presumes that the decision
to invest in risk management and the benefit of this
investment occur contemporaneously. There is, how-
ever, no consensus in the theoretical literature that
oneperiod results can be transferred to intertemporal
settings. To address this gap, we study the effect of an
increase in risk aversion on the demand for risk
management in a twoperiod context. Our findings
reproduce the oneperiod results and, thus, support the
focus of previous empirical literature on the structure
of the risk rather than on the timing of investments
and benefits. We also contrast our results with those
obtained by employing widely used but limited pre-
ferences to examine risk aversion in intertemporal
settings (standard additive expected utility setting,
Selden, Epstein and Zin).
KEYWORDS
comparative risk aversion, saving, selfinsurance, selfprotection
JEL CLASSIFICATION
D61, D81, D91
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits use, distribution and
reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
© 2021 The Authors. Journal of Risk and Insurance published by Wiley Periodicals LLC on behalf of American Risk and Insurance
Association.
1|INTRODUCTION
The decision to invest in risk management involves the consideration of risk and uncertainty.
Individuals can prevent car accidents by driving carefully or by applying what is learned in a
defensive driving course, reduce the risk of a fire by installing sprinkler systems or lightning
conductors, and eat well and exercise regularly to reduce health risks. Companies invest in
cybersecurity to prevent successful cyberattacks, install burglar alarms to reduce the risk of
theft, and, in the case of farming, store extra water in the event of a drought. Moreover, both
individuals and companies obtain insurance to mitigate financial losses. Given the numerous
examples of risk management activities, how can we use observed behavior to draw inferences
about the underlying risk preferences of decision makers?
Mitigation decisions usually involve activities to reduce either the size or the probability of loss.
We follow Ehrlich and Becker (1972) and call the former selfinsurance and the latter self
protection.
1
While previous research supports to employ selfinsurance decisions to infer risk
preferences, it identifies intricacies to draw inferences from selfprotection activities. Theoretical
findings show that greater risk aversion raises optimal selfinsurance but has an ambiguous effect
on optimal selfprotection in oneperiod models (Briys & Schlesinger, 1990; Dionne &
Eeckhoudt, 1985). In this setting, the investment in risk management and the induced risk re-
duction are assumed to occur contemporaneously, but, often, for example, when buying insurance
or when making safety investments, they occur temporally separated.
This paper employs a twoperiod model to incorporate the time structure of investments
in risk management and their benefits. The objective is to study how optimal risk man-
agement changes with increased risk aversion. This comes with the conceptual challenge of
how to compare risk preferences in a twoperiod model. Kihlstrom and Mirman (1974)
demonstrate that comparing agents in terms of their risk aversion requires keeping ordinal
preferences unchanged. Preferences also need to fulfill a monotonicity property to ensure
that agents do not prefer firstorder stochastically dominated lotteries (Bommier
et al., 2012,2017). Theoretical research, however, widely employs risk preferences that are
either not consistent with ordinal preferences (standard additive expected utility setting) or
not necessarily monotone (Epstein & Zin, 1989;Selden,1978). In contrast, our approach to
comparative risk aversion in intertemporal settings fulfills both requirements.
First, we find that increased risk aversion unambiguously raises optimal selfinsurance,
using a framework provided by Bommier et al. (2012), which works only with ordinal pre-
ferences and does not assume a particular representation of risk preferences. To study the
interaction between saving and selfinsurance, we further employ the preferences proposed by
Kihlstrom and Mirman (1974). In this setting, we demonstrate that a more riskaverse agent
invests more in selfinsurance with and without endogenous saving. Second, we study self
protection decisions. While Bommier et al.'s approach remains silent about the effect of greater
risk aversion on selfprotection, Kihlstrom and Mirman's preferences enable us to draw con-
clusions about this effect. Both with and without endogenous saving, we show that, if the loss
probability is sufficiently small, a more riskaverse agent invests more in selfprotection. We
further contrast our results with those obtained by employing widely used but limited
1
Insurance is, for example, a special case of selfinsurance and has similar comparative statics (Courbage et al., 2013).
Additionally, note that decision makers in Ehrlich and Becker's (1972) setting are assumed to have precise information
about the benefits of risk mitigation. In contrast, Li and Peter (2021) analyze selfinsurance and selfprotection activities
where the effectiveness of risk mitigation is subject to exogenous environmental factors.
98
|
HUBER
preferences to examine risk aversion in intertemporal settings (standard additive expected
utility setting, Selden, Epstein and Zin).
Our results contribute to both theoretical and empirical literature. Bommier et al. (2012)show
that standard additive expected utility settings as well as Selden's (1978) and Epstein and Zin's
(1989) preferences are not well ordered in terms of risk aversion. We explore how the lack thereof
affects optimal risk management under an increase in risk aversion. Without the consistency of
ordinal preferences (standard additive expected utility setting) or the lack of monotonicity (Selden,
Epstein and Zin), we find that twoperiod results for risk management hinge on the consideration
of endogenous saving. Agents who optimize risk management and saving separately (employing
two mental accounts) would then behave differently than would agents, who optimize risk man-
agement and saving jointly (employing only one mental account). Using preferences that are well
ordered in terms of risk aversion, however, we reproduce the oneperiod results in our twoperiod
models independent of the consideration of endogenous saving. Our findings are thus good news
for empiricists. Empirical studies often ignore the intricacies of the time structure when analyzing
mitigation decisions and simply assume all costs and benefits to appear contemporaneously. They
thus make the implicit assumption that results of oneperiod models can be transferred to inter-
temporal settings. Our analysis, therefore, supports the focus of the empirical literature on the
structure of the risk rather than on the timing of investments and benefits.
Risk management in twoperiod settings has received only scant attention in the literature.
Menegatti (2009) was the first to study selfprotection in a twoperiod setting, finding that
prudence is positively related to investments in selfprotection. By introducing endogenous
saving, Peter (2017) reproduces the oneperiod result and explains his finding through the
substitution effect between selfprotection and saving (Menegatti & Rebessi, 2011). The paper
most closely related to ours is Hofmann and Peter (2016), who study selfinsurance and self
protection in a twoperiod expected utility framework with and without saving. In the absence
of saving, the authors find that, if firstperiod consumption is sufficiently high, a more concave
utility function raises optimal selfinsurance and optimal selfprotection. They show that, in the
presence of saving, if the loss probability is sufficiently low, higher concavity unambiguously
increases optimal selfinsurance and optimal selfprotection. Increasing the concavity of the
utility function, however, changes ordinal preferences in a standard additive expected utility
setting, which makes it impossible to study the effect of risk aversion on optimal selfinsurance
and optimal selfprotection. We address this gap and contribute to the literature by focusing on
the role of greater risk aversion on optimal risk management in isolation.
In Section 2, we first summarize Bommier et al.'s (2012) framework of comparative risk
aversion. We then examine the effect of greater risk aversion on selfinsurance and self
protection decisions, using monotone preferences in Section 3and employing nonmonotone
preferences in Section 4. We discuss our findings in view of the extant literature in Section 5.
The paper ends with concluding remarks and directions for future research in Section 6. All
proofs appear in Appendix A.
2|COMPARATIVE RISK AVERSION IN TWO PERIODS
2.1 |Overview
According to comparative ArrowPratt risk aversion, an agent A is more riskaverse than agent
B if A's utility function is more concave than B's (Arrow, 1963; Pratt, 1964). While greater
HUBER
|
99

Get this document and AI-powered insights with a free trial of vLex and Vincent AI

Get Started for Free

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant

  • Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database

  • Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength

  • Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities

  • Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

vLex

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT