COME ON IN, THE WATER'S FINE! AN EXPERIMENTAL EXAMINATION OF HYBRID IPO AUCTIONS WITH A PUBLIC POOL

Published date01 March 2019
AuthorMinjie Shao,Ann E. Sherman,Charles R. Schnitzlein
Date01 March 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jfir.12169
COME ON IN, THE WATERS FINE! AN EXPERIMENTAL EXAMINATION OF
HYBRID IPO AUCTIONS WITH A PUBLIC POOL
Charles R. Schnitzlein
University of Vermont
Minjie Shao
Tusculum University
Ann E. Sherman
DePaul University
Abstract
We offer experimental and theoretical evidence that auction methods for initial public
offerings (IPOs) in the United States may be improved through hybrids that include a
separate retail tranche or public pool.The multi-unit uniform price auctions in our
laboratory experimentsincorporate key IPO features includingendogenous entry, costly
informationacquisition, and differing capacityconstraints. As predicted,hybrids increase
proceedsand reduce price volatility, price error, and the incentivefor small bidders to free
ride. Underpricing occurs in bothtreatments but is attenuated with the public pool. Our
results imply that both IPO auctions and equity crowdfunding/crowdinvesting should
include separate, non-price-setting tranches for the general public.
JEL Classification: C92, D02, D44, G02
I. Introduction
The method used for initial public offerings (IPOs) in the United States, known as book
building, has long been controversial because of the magnitude of average underpricing, the
variability of initial returns, and the conicts of interest between issuers and underwriters.
Ritter (2011) discusses the CLAS controversies (Commissions for IPOs, Laddering, Analyst
conicts of interest, and Spinning) and argues that agency problems between issuers and
underwriters are of rst-order importance in explaining the magnitude of underpricing,
leading to questionable allocation practices that preclude participation by many investors.
1
We thank conference participants at the 2015 meeting of the Financial Management Association and seminar
participants at the University of Central Florida, Ivey Business School, Iowa State University, and the University of
Iowa for helpful comments.
1
In contrast, Sherman (2000) models the effect of the one price rule for U.S. IPOs when there is more than one
type of investor. If IPO shares must be underpriced for some investors (e.g., to attract attention or induce costly
evaluation), the one price rule means that other investors get excess returns unless the underwriter can somehow
recapture some of that excess. Thus, many of the allocation practices described by Ritter (2011)may occur without
affecting the underpricing level. See also Loughran and Ritter (2004) for discussion of the scandals and overall
trends in IPO underpricing, and Ritter and Welch (2002), Ljungqvist (2007), and Wilhelm (2005) for reviews of the
academic IPO literature.
The Journal of Financial Research Vol. XLII, No. 1 Pages 539 Spring 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jfir.12169
5
© 2019 The Southern Finance Association and the Southwestern Finance Association
Many have suggested auctions as an alternative, given the success of auctions in other
nancial markets, such as government debt securities. After all, the surest way to prevent
agency conicts is to take decisions out of the hands of the agent, which is what a standard
sealed bid auction does for IPO pricingit uses preestablished rules to price the shares based
on bids, rather than giving discretion to the underwriter. IPO auctions offer transparent
allocation and pricing rules, and open access to retail investors.
Yet auction IPOs have not been popular in the United States. There have been a
total of 23 IPO auctions in the United States since the method was rst introduced by the
investment bank WR Hambrecht in 1999. The auction method has been used for
prominent IPOs such as Google (2004) and Morningstar (2005); for tech/Internet IPOs
such as Andover.net (1999), Salon.com (1999), Bank of the Internet (2005), Netsuite
(2007), and Rackspace Hosting (2008); and for consumer-oriented, easily relatable
companies such as Ravenswood Winery (1999), Peets Coffee (2001), Overstock (2002),
and Truett-Hurst Winery (2013). Despite being used over time by a variety of companies,
the auction method has not taken off in the United States and has not been commonly
chosen by issuers. A public pool would involve setting aside a xed number of shares for
retail investors, who could then participate in the IPO at the same price as investors in the
auction tranche. Our research indicates that a public pool would make the auction method
more attractive to both issuers and investors by increasing the expected proceeds for the
issuer and reducing risk for all involved.
The auction method has similarly struggled outside the United States. Sealed
bid auctions have been tried for IPOs in more than two dozen countries, but issuers
have consistently abandoned the auction method in favor of other alternatives.
2
The
experimentation with new IPO methods such as auctions began with the trend in the
1980s and 1990s toward privatization of formerly government-owned companies in
areas such as telecommunications. Auctions were often initially popular for IPOs,
but then issuers returned to their traditional method, the xed-price public offer.
3
Most countries later adopted the book-building method that originated in the United
States.
4
Although it has been rare for IPO issuers to choose the auction method
voluntarily over the last decade, regulations in Vietnam, China, and Taiwan mandate
their use. The auction method has long been required for IPOs in Vietnam, a country that
is still transitioning away from a planned economy through the privatization of state-
owned enterprises. Sequential hybrid uniform price auctions have been required in China
2
Jagannathan, Jirnyi, and Sherman (2015) document the disappearance of auction IPOs and nd that it was
not driven by regulatory changes that restricted their use (although in some cases, such as France and Japan, the
shift was made possible by regulations allowing greater use of other methods).
3
A public offer, also known as an open offer, a universal offer, or often simply as the IPO method,is one in
which the price is set in advance and the issuer/underwriter does not have discretion regarding individual
allocations. Typically, the process is open to all retail investors in the country on a more or less equal basis, and
balloting (a type of lottery) is used to allocate shares in case of oversubscription. A public offer is strictly an
allocation method, as opposed to a price-setting method.
4
Whereas Doidge, Karolyi, and Stulz (2013) show that U.S. IPOs have become less important around the
world over the past two decades, Jagannathan, Jirnyi, and Sherman (2015) show that the U.S. IPO method has
become dominant.
6 The Journal of Financial Research
since at least 2009 (see Cao et al. 2016). As of January 1, 2016, uniform price auctions are
required for large IPOs (more than NT$400 million in proceeds) in Taiwan.
Given the many well-established advantages of auctions and yet their consistent
unpopularity for IPOs, one explanation for this discrepancy is that the standard sealed bid
auction format is not as well suited to IPOs as to, say, Treasury securities. Price discovery
is less of an issue for Treasury securities, which are high-quality debt instruments that are
already trading in many forms (the when issued market, the off the run issue, etc.), with a
stable number of large dealers that bid for them regularly. IPO rms tend to be small,
young companies that have not been traded, and are likely to grow and change
dramatically and unpredictably in the next few years. They come from a variety of
industries and appeal to different sets of investors. Such different securities may require a
different auction format.
5
Thus, it is worth exploring ways to design auctions that are better suited to an
IPO environment. The rst study to model this is by Biais and Faugeron-Crouzet (2002),
who explore the effects of the frequent IPO auction practice of setting the offer price
strictly below the market-clearing price (known as a dirtyauction or as leaving
something on the table). We focus on another common feature of IPOsthe use of
hybrids, with separate retail tranches or public pools.
6
Our article offers experimental and
theoretical evidence that the inclusion of a public pool may improve the auction method
for IPOs by reducing risk for both bidders and the issuer.
We rst examine the extent to which free riding, inaccurate pricing, and
variability in auction outcomes arise in a uniform price auction with endogenous costly
information acquisition. Next, we determine whether the introduction of a public pool
tranche can be used to reduce the problems that have been identied. We accomplish this
by conducting a laboratory experiment that incorporates key features of an IPO auction
environment, including endogenous entry and bidders of different bidding capacities. A
major advantage of experimental over real-worldbidding data is that we know the
information set and budget constraints of each bidder and thus do not have to speculate
over, for example, whether a bidder is informed. The hypotheses we test are based on the
use of simulations to identify the symmetric Bayesian Nash equilibrium (SBNE) for both
pure and hybrid auctions.
7
5
The differences are even wider between Treasury securities and equity investments in early-stage private
companies. Thus, this research has implications for the equity crowdfunding made possible in the United States by
the Jumpstart Our Business Startups (JOBS) Act, including Regulation Aþofferings. These implications are
discussed briey in the Conclusion.
6
These public pools originated from the traditional xed-price public offer method, where investors could ask
for share allocations but were not involved in setting the offer price. Given the long tradition of allowing all retail
investors to order shares in each IPO, most countries that experimented with rst the auction and then the book-
building method continued to allow retail investors to participatein much the same way as beforethrough a
retail tranche or public pool. Thus, hybrid IPOs with a public pool are common internationally, although generally
the book-building rather than the auction method is used to set the offer price.
7
Throughout this article, we use the term symmetricto mean symmetric within each investor group, given
that our experiments each have four large and four small bidders, with different capacity constraints. Thus, we
consider a set of strategies to be symmetric even if large and small bidders follow different strategies, as long as
there are no strategy differences within each size group.
Hybrid IPO Auctions with a Public Pool 7

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT